output gap

Error message

  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Deprecated function: The each() function is deprecated. This message will be suppressed on further calls in _menu_load_objects() (line 579 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/menu.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Deprecated function: implode(): Passing glue string after array is deprecated. Swap the parameters in drupal_get_feeds() (line 394 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).

Robert Solow on 'Why Economies Grow'

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Sun, 10/05/2020 - 9:32pm in

As a follow-up and companion piece to my previous post, I decided to publish a transcription of a lecture on economic growth by Robert Solow that I transcribed originally as an aid for friends and colleagues who were studying economics. Although the lecture was given by Prof. Solow a few years ago during the height of the financial crisis, it contains loads of timeless insights, some of which is useful to be reminded of in the current situation, as discussions about the output gap resume in the next few years (see chart).

However, it's extremely important to keep in mind that in our current predicament as a result of covid potential GDP will also likely take a huge hit, as businesses and employees require some catching up in terms of business practices (misaligned with changing consumer preferences) and job training (due to skills entropy from employees being on furlough), to name only a few aspects that are likely to be impacted. In many ways, the post-covid period will bring us back to the type of economic analysis that used to occur a long time ago when natural catastrophes had significant and frequent impacts on economies' productive capacities.

The video of the lecture is included down below, though the sound quality is very bad, which is why I recommend reading the transcription instead (and you'll get through the transcript much faster by reading it).

Key insights are highlighted in bold font. Enjoy!

The business of this course is the long run. What are the
sources of economic growth in the national economy or in the larger economy?
Where does growth come from? And the policy implication – well, not implication,
but policy question – is ‘How do you get an economy to grow rapidly and to have
that growth widely shared in the nation?’
But there is a problem – it is a problem that appeared in
the slides that Prof Newstone showed. It is a problem about getting there from
here. So I’m going to start by talking a little bit about right now – this is
not going to be the usual stuff about the financial crisis and all that – I
have something else in mind.

There is something very odd about our economic situation in
the US today. I read just recently an estimate from the Federal Reserve that
about $7 trillion worth of wealth has been destroyed in the last year or year
in a half (in 2008-2009). The country, so to speak, is $7 trillion poorer than it
was.

When I wasn’t having a conversation with Cathy in the car, I
was trying to divide 7 trillion by 300 million--the population of the US--in my
head. It comes to about $23,000 for every man, woman and child in the country. Some,
of course, have lost more, some have lost less.

What I want to point out is how strange that is: $7 trillion
of wealth has gone down the drain but the productive capacity of the US economy
– the capacity of our system to produce goods and service for its people –
hasn’t diminished at all. In fact, it is undoubtedly higher than it was a year
ago or 18 months ago: the labour force is a couple percent larger, the skills
and education and training of the population is certainly not deteriorating and
have probably gained. The net investment in capital has been positive – it’s
been declining – but has been positive.

So we have a bigger stock of productive capital in the
economy now than we did a year ago or 18 months ago. So the productive capacity
of this economy is bigger than it was, despite of this $7 trillion of
disappearance of wealth. If you are thinking of buying the US economy as a gift
for your boyfriend or girlfriend, it would be worth just as much as it was
worth – you know, like a used car – it would be worth just about as much as it
was worth a year ago.

So in that sense we haven’t lost anything at all. But, of
course, the point is we are in a recession. It is one year old according to
pundits. And according to other pundits, or the same pundits, it’ll continue
for at least until the second half of this year and maybe beyond. And the point
is we are not using the productive capacity that we have.

You saw the unemployment numbers that Professor Newstone
showed you. It is a lot harder to measure excess capacity in industry than it
is to measure unemployment, but there are such figures, and they show an
increase in unused capacity. So we have this machine for producing the goods
and services for the population and we are not making full use of it. And that
under-use of economic capacity, of productive capacity will go on for a long
time. Even if the economy turns up in the second half of this year we will
undoubtedly finish 2010 still with some slack in the economy because the slack
disappears only gradually. 

So if you are interested – now, this is the point, this is
why I started this way – if we are thinking about the long run growth of the
economy (which means the long run growth of its capacity to produce), it’s not
a separate but it’s an analytically slightly different problem to make sure
that that capacity is used.

As long as we are not using all of the capacity that we
have, the economy and the decision-makers in the economy are not likely to be
motivated to do the things that increase potential output, that increase the
productive capacity very rapidly.

So the short-run order of business – policy business – for
us and every other rich country in Europe or Asia right now is to close that
gap or narrow that gap between productive capacity and actual output, which
means fundamentally trying to increase the demand for goods and services. And
to do that in a way that at least doesn’t create obstacles to the long-run
growth of the economy once the gap is closed, and maybe does some things that
will help it.

So, imagine it is now January 2011 and the American economy
and the economies of the other rich countries – developed countries of the
world – are prospering reasonably well, are using their capacity, have closed
that gap. Then the question is: What makes them grow? What economic activities
that take place have the effect of increasing the capacity of the economy to
produce useful goods and services? 

Now, you won’t be surprised – in fact, I’m staring at this
monitor here and it says: so what determines the rate of economic growth in the
economy? And that’s the question that I want to come to now, and it becomes
relevant after we have done the short run task of closing that gap. There isn’t
any one word or two word answer to that question. 

And I should make it explicit that I am thinking now about
what determines the rate of economic growth in a rich economy, in an advanced
industrial economy. I am not thinking about developing economies where the
answers are related but the answers are somewhat different.

And the truth is that for an advanced economy the answers to
that question – what are the sources of growth of national output, of productive
capacity – are really the usual suspects. They are things we have known about
now for quite a long time. And basically, what matters is what you might
describe as investment in a very broad sense. I have to emphasize “in a very
broad sense”.

What increases the productive of an economy like ours is
investment in physical capital, in machinery, in computers and all the rest of
that, investment in what economists call human capital, meaning skills and
capacities of workers and people who work in the economy, and investment in new
technology.

And here there is a slight difference between the US and
even most of the countries in Europe. Not quite across the board but in most
branches of industry the US is the technological leader. The gap was very big
at the end of the Second World War and has closed considerably. But still, if
you look at sector by sector, with some exceptions, the US is the technological
leader.

Other countries of the world, that were even fairly rich
countries have the luxury of being able to acquire technology by innovation,
essentially by adopting, using what is already known. This country (i.e., the US)
is in the position of having – so to speak – to invent its own future.

So basically, if we are looking now at the US, the things we
have to look after in order to have a successful fairly high rate of growth (we
can talk about the equity issues later) are a high rate of savings and investment
in plant and equipment. I’d rather have the saving done here than abroad so
that, in effect, the capital equipment that is built by investment in this
country is owned in this country, and the returns to it stay in this country.
It’s not necessary but it’s probably desirable. 

We need an extraordinary amount of emphasis – and we’ll talk
more about this later – on investment in human capital, on producing the labour
force that has the skills that are necessary to successfully operate that plant
and equipment. And that is especially important because a country like this
also has to invest in new technology. There is no place it can copy from – it
has to in most cases create it itself.

Now, when I say new technology, the phrase tends to have a
“high tech” air about it. But I don’t mean it that way.  New technology needn’t be high tech. It turns
out that – in many ways – the most important contributors to productivity in
the US over the last decade or two have been the application of information
technology to wholesale trade, retail trade and financial services.

In fact, there are studies trying to understand why the
major, big European economies, Germany, France, UK and Italy have lagged behind
the US in productivity terms, general productivity terms. And the common answer
seems to be that they have been slow to adapt the information technology to the
service sectors. In manufacturing, there is very little gap, if any. But the
gap is in the service sectors. 

So, this is extremely important. And I want to emphasize it,
even at the risk of some repetition. One of the standard, valid, almost
universal generalizations about the way people behave economically is that
technically the income elasticity of the demand for services is high. All over
the world, as incomes rise, personal incomes rise, people want to spend, [and] choose
to spend a larger fraction of that income on services rather than goods. And
you can understand why that should be so.

So this means that most of the rapidly growing advanced
economies grow more rapidly in the service-producing sectors than in the
goods-producing sector. There are exceptions to that. A country like Germany – to
a lesser extent Japan, or formally Japan, not so much anymore – has a strong bias
toward trying to make its living from simply exporting high quality
manufactured goods. You notice I said exporting because the population of
Germany, like the population of anywhere else, wants to consume services as it
gets rich, not goods.

So those are the things, the essentially important things
that a country like the US needs to do to generate long-run growth of
productive capacity. 

I should say, in terms of policy, that you should beware of
any universal advice like “well, the market will take care of that”. You know,
if the alternative to the free-market economy is some kind of central planning,
there is no question to where the advantage lies. But there is absolutely no
evidence in the historical record of the advanced economies that zero
regulation or weak regulation of industry is somehow conducive to rapid growth,
or that minimal involvement of the government in the economy is conducive to
rapid growth.

The functions of the government in terms of long run growth
are just what you would deduce from what I have already said: promoting
research and development, providing incentives for investment when they are
lacking, taking care of education, and looking after mobility. By the way, it
is probably also true that a country – there is less evidence for this
generalization, but it’s probably also true – that business cycle instability
is bad for economic growth.

For countries that are given to wide fluctuations like the
ones we were looking at a few minutes ago, that’s not helpful for long-run
growth because it adds to uncertainty. The likelihood of broad fluctuations
adds to uncertainty is bad for all forward looking activities, like investment,
like mobility, like education.

I wanted to say one more thing about the issue of mobility. When
I say mobility, I mean industrial mobility and occupational mobility. In a
rapidly growing, technologically-based economy, people have to change the
nature of their jobs frequently and capital has to flow freely from obsolescent
industries to new industries.

It is very important when you come in this course to talk
about issues of equity. I think it is very important to find ways so that the
burdens that are associated with necessary mobility don’t fall on workers and
other people who are ill-equipped to prepare them [for that eventuality].

Dislocation and sometimes dislocation is probably an
inevitable part of fast, mainly technologically-based growth. But it is the
task of economic policy to find ways of combining that with income security, up
to now, where it’s mostly below the median for incomes.

Ben Bernanke and the natural rate of interest

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Tue, 31/03/2015 - 12:07pm in

From Professor Bernanke to Governor Bernanke to Chairman Bernanke to Ben Bernanke, Blogger. Quite the progression!

I enjoyed reading Ben Bernanke's blog post today. But it doesn't appear everyone thinks like me. I noticed some have criticized Bernanke for using the concept of the equilibrium (or natural) rate of interest, or the real rate of interest consistent with output at its potential level and with stable prices.

Now, I realize that the equilibrium real rate is unobservable and varies through time, which means it's subject to uncertainty. However, we could say the same thing about the concept of potential output, yet few would deny it is a useful concept.

In fact, most people are aware of the concept of "output gap", the difference between potential output and actual output. The corollary concept for the real interest rate is the "interest rate gap", the deviation of the actual policy rate from the real equilibrium rate.

This is essentially what Bernanke was driving at in his post today. Simply, the interest rate gap is a measure of the stance of monetary policy: a large (small) gap means monetary policy is loose (tight).

Back in the Keynesian era, policymakers used the concept of the "full employment surplus" (FES), or the budgetary surplus consistent with full employment, as a way to illustrate how the actual budget deficit wasn't being caused by a lack of tax revenue or out of control government spending but rather was caused by the weakness of the economy and the lack of output due to unemployed and idle resources. I view the interest rate gap in a similar way. Whereas the FES provided a useful measure of the stance of fiscal policy by highlighting the difference between the actual "surplus" (or negative surplus in the case of a deficit) and the FES, the interest rate gap provides a useful measure of the stance of monetary policy.

But don't get me wrong. In no way does any of this mean that central banks should be rigid in adjusting their policy rate to track the estimated equilibrium real rate.

As far as I'm concerned, central bankers should use their judgement and consider all information, not just their estimates of the real equilibrium rate and interest rate gap. For instance, if a central bank's estimate of the real equilibrium rate shows it is rising, yet inflation isn't, it may not be the right time to increase the policy rate.

Similarly, if a central bank's estimate of the equilibrium rate shows it is remaining stable, yet unemployment is rising, it may be entirely justified for the central bank to keep its policy rate at the same level or even to reduce it. I'm of the same view when it comes to the concept of the natural rate of unemployment: using it properly requires good judgement.

A final note on Bernanke's comment about how large deficits tend to increase the equilibrium real rate given that government borrowing diverts savings away from private investment. One thing I noticed is that Bernanke carefully added that this would occur "if everything else stays equal". In other words, this means he's not denying that a different (or even, opposite) effect could occur if other forces are at work.

For instance, the opposite effect could occur if budget deficits, by sustaining business activity, reduce default risk on corporate bonds and subsequently narrow the spread between the yields on corporate and government bonds, thus helping to reduce the cost of capital to the private sector. In such a scenario, budget deficits have effectively "crowded-in" private sector spending. I doubt Bernanke would deny that budget deficits could have such an effect.