Monetary policy

Error message

  • Deprecated function: The each() function is deprecated. This message will be suppressed on further calls in _menu_load_objects() (line 579 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/menu.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Deprecated function: implode(): Passing glue string after array is deprecated. Swap the parameters in drupal_get_feeds() (line 394 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).

Quantifying the macroeconomic impact of geopolitical risk

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Wed, 24/04/2024 - 6:00pm in

Julian Reynolds

Policymakers and market participants consistently cite geopolitical developments as a key risk to the global economy and financial system. But how can one quantify the potential macroeconomic effects of these developments? Applying local projections to a popular metric of geopolitical risk, I show that geopolitical risk weighs on GDP in the central case and increases the severity of adverse outcomes. This impact appears much larger in emerging market economies (EMEs) than advanced economies (AEs). Geopolitical risk also pushes up inflation in both central case and adverse outcomes, implying that macroeconomic policymakers have to trade-off stabilising output versus inflation. Finally, I show that geopolitical risk may transmit to output and inflation via trade and uncertainty channels.

How has the global geopolitical outlook evolved?

Risks from geopolitical tensions have become of increasing concern to policymakers and market participants this decade.

A popular metric to monitor these risks is the Geopolitical Risk (GPR) Index constructed by Caldara and Iacoviello (2022). The authors construct their index using automated text-search results from newspaper articles. Namely, they search for words relevant to their definition of geopolitical risk, such as ‘crisis’, ‘terrorism’ or ‘war’. They also construct GPR indices at a disaggregated country-specific level, based on joint occurrences of key words and specific countries.

Chart 1 plots the evolution of the geopolitical risks over time. Most notably, the Global GPR Index (black line) spikes following the 11 September attacks. More recently, this index shows a sharp increase following Russia’s invasion of Ukraine in February 2022.

Country-specific indices typically co-move significantly with the Global index but may deviate when country-specific risks arise. For instance, the UK-specific (aqua line) and France-specific indices (orange line) show more pronounced spikes following terrorist attacks in London and Paris respectively, while the Germany-specific index (purple line) rises particularly strongly following the invasion of Ukraine.

Chart 1: Global and country-specific Geopolitical Risk Indices

The GPR index is similar to the Economic Policy Uncertainty (EPU) index, produced by Baker, Bloom and Davis. The EPU index is also constructed based on a text search from newspaper articles, and available at both a global and country-specific level. But it measures more generic uncertainty related to economic policymaking, besides uncertainty stemming from geopolitical developments.

How to quantify the macroeconomic impact of these developments?

In light of increasing concerns about geopolitical tension, a growing body of literature aims to quantify the macro-financial impact of these developments. For instance, Aiyar et al (2023) examine multiple transmission channels of ‘geoeconomic fragmentation’ – a policy-driven reversal of global economic integration – including trade, capital flows and technology diffusion. Also Caldara and Iacoviello (2022) employ a range of empirical techniques to examine how shocks to their GPR affect macroeconomic variables.

These studies unambiguously show that geopolitical tension has adverse effects on macroeconomic activity and contributes to greater downside risks. But empirical estimates tend to differ significantly, depending on the nature and severity of scenarios through which geopolitical tensions may play out.

My approach focusses on the impact of geopolitical risks on a range of macroeconomic variables. Namely, I use local projections (Jordà (2005)), an econometric approach which examines how a given variable responds in the future to changes in geopolitical risk today. I employ a panel data set of AEs and EMEs (listed in Table A), with quarterly data from 1985 onwards.

Table A: List of economies

Notes: Countries divided into Advanced and Emerging Market Economies as per IMF classification. Country-level EPU indices available for starred economies.

Following Caldara and Iacoviello (2022), I regress a given variable on the country-level GPR index, controlling for: country-level fixed effects; the global GPR index; the first lag of my variable of interest; and the first lags of (four-quarter) GDP growth, consumer price inflation, oil price inflation, and changes in central bank policy rates.

I use ordinary least squares estimation to estimate the mean response over time of a given macroeconomic variable to geopolitical risk. But to assess the impact of geopolitical risk at the tail of the distribution, I follow Lloyd et al (2021) and Garofalo et al (2023) by using local-projection quantile regression. This latter approach uses an outlook-at-risk framework to illustrate how severe the impact of geopolitical risk could be under extreme circumstances.

How does geopolitical risk affect GDP growth and inflation?

Chart 2 show the impact of geopolitical risk on average annual GDP growth across my panel of economies. In the mean results (aqua line), a one standard deviation increase in geopolitical risks is expected to reduce GDP growth by 0.2 percentage points (pp) at peak. But at the 5th percentile – a one-in-twenty adverse outcome – GDP growth falls by almost 0.5pp. In other words, this means that geopolitical risk both weighs on GDP growth but also increases the severity of tail-risk outcomes, adding to the global risk environment.

The magnitude of these effects is somewhat smaller than Caldara and Iacoviello (2022), though they use a longer time sample (1900 onwards), which includes both World Wars.

Chart 2: Dynamic impact of geopolitical risk on GDP growth

Notes: Shaded areas denote 68% confidence interval around Mean and 5th percentile estimates.

The impact of geopolitical risks on GDP growth is heterogeneous across AEs and EMEs. Chart 3 plots the impact of geopolitical risk at the one-year horizon for both groups of economies, at the mean and 5th percentile. For AEs, the mean impact of geopolitical risk on GDP growth appears to be negligible, though the 5th percentile impact is more noticeable. For EMEs, however, both the mean and 5th percentile impact of geopolitical risk are material. This result is consistent with Aiyar et al (2023), who show that EMEs are also more sensitive to geoeconomic fragmentation in the medium term.

Chart 3: Impacts of geopolitical risk on GDP growth at one-year horizon, by country group

Notes: Shaded areas denote 68% confidence interval around Mean and 5th percentile estimates.

I also find that geopolitical risk tends to raise consumer price inflation, consistent with Caldara et al (2024) and Pinchetti and Smith (2024). This could pose a challenging trade-off for a macroeconomic policymaker, between stabilising output versus inflation.

Chart 4 shows that at the mean, average annual inflation rises by 0.5pp at peak, following a geopolitical risk shock. But at the 95th percentile (one-in-twenty high inflation outcome), inflation rises by 1.4pp. As with GDP, the inflationary impact of geopolitical risk shocks appears to be larger for EMEs, though the mean impact on AE inflation is also statistically significant (Chart 5).

Chart 4: Dynamic impact of geopolitical risk on consumer price inflation

Notes: Shaded areas denote 68% confidence interval around Mean and 95th percentile estimates.

Chart 5: Impact of geopolitical risk on consumer price inflation at one-year horizon, by country group

Notes: Shaded areas denote 68% confidence interval around Mean and 5th percentile estimates.

What are the potential transmission channels?

One key channel through which geopolitical risk could transmit to GDP and inflation may be disruption to global commodity markets, particularly energy. Pinchetti and Smith (2024) highlight energy supply as a key transmission channel of geopolitical risk, which pushes up on inflation. Energy price shocks could also have significant effects on GDP and inflation in adverse scenarios (Garofalo et al (2023)).

The inflationary impulse following Russia’s invasion of Ukraine marks an extreme instance of commodity market disruption (Martin and Reynolds (2023)). Sensitivity analysis suggests that even excluding this period, geopolitical risk still has trade-off inducing implications for inflation and GDP.

I also find that geopolitical risk leads to significant disruption in world trade, a channel also highlighted by Aiyar et al (2023). Chart 6 plots the estimated impacts on trade volumes growth (measured by imports), while Chart 7 plots the impact on trade price inflation (measured by export deflators). These results imply that both trade volumes and prices are highly sensitive to global geopolitical risk. The peak response of trade volumes growth to geopolitical risk is around three times greater than GDP, at the mean and 5th percentile. And the peak response of export price inflation – representing the basket of tradeable goods and services – is significantly greater than that of consumer prices, at the mean and 95th percentile.

This implies that countries are likely to be exposed to global geopolitical risk via the effect on trading partners: falling import volumes for Country A means that Country B’s exports fall, weighing on GDP; higher export prices for County A means that Country B imports higher inflation from Country A.

Chart 6: Dynamic impact of geopolitical risk on trade volumes growth

Notes: Shaded areas denote 68% confidence interval around Mean and 5th percentile estimates.

Chart 7: Dynamic impact of geopolitical risk on trade price inflation

Notes: Shaded areas denote 68% confidence interval around Mean and 95th percentile estimates.

Finally, I find that greater geopolitical risk is associated with somewhat greater economic uncertainty. Chart 8 shows the response of country-specific EPU indices (compiled by Baker, Bloom and Davis) to an increase in geopolitical risk. This implies a mean cumulative increase in uncertainty of around 0.1 standard deviations; the peak impact at the 95th percentile is twice as great.

This impact, while statistically significant, appears relatively small in an absolute sense. For context, the US-specific EPU index rose by two standard deviations between 2017 and 2019, after the onset of the US-China trade war. Nonetheless, it is plausible that uncertainty may be a key transmission channel for geopolitical tensions in the medium term, which may particularly weigh on business investment (Manuel et al (2021)).

Chart 8: Dynamic impact of geopolitical risk on economic policy uncertainty

Notes: Shaded areas denote 68% confidence interval around Mean and 95th percentile estimates.

Conclusion

This post presents empirical evidence which quantifies the potential macroeconomic effects of geopolitical developments. Geopolitical risk weighs on GDP growth, in both the central case and tail-risk scenarios, and is also likely to raise inflation via a number of channels.

Further studies may look to refine the identification of geopolitical risk shocks, to purge the underlying series of endogenous relationships with macroeconomic variables. Further analysis may also be helpful to substantiate why EMEs appear more sensitive to geopolitical risk than AEs, particularly transmission via financial conditions and capital flows. Given the heightening geopolitical tensions that policymakers have highlighted, further research into the macro-financial implications of these tensions is highly important at this juncture.

Julian Reynolds works in the Bank’s Stress Testing and Resilience Group.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk or leave a comment below.

Comments will only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

To the lower bound and back: measuring UK monetary conditions

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 11/04/2024 - 6:00pm in

Natalie Burr, Julian Reynolds and Mike Joyce

Monetary policymakers have a number of tools they can use to influence monetary conditions, in order to maintain price stability. While central banks typically favour short-term policy rates as their primary instrument, when policy rates remained constrained at near-zero levels following the global financial crisis (GFC), many central banks – including the Bank of England – turned to unconventional policies to further ease monetary conditions. How can the combined effect of these policies be measured? This post presents one possible metric – a Monetary Conditions Index – that uses a data-driven approach to summarise information from a range of variables related to the conduct of UK monetary policy. We discuss what this implies about how UK monetary conditions have evolved since the GFC.

What are monetary conditions?

The idea of constructing a Monetary Conditions Index (UK MCI) – a summary metric of variables related to the conduct of monetary policy – is not new.

Traditionally, monetary conditions were defined as a combination of information from short-term interest rates and exchange rates (eg Batini and Turnbull (2000)). Earlier literature on MCIs therefore typically focused on a small number of variables.

This approach has become less defensible as many central banks – including the Bank of England – extended their toolkit with a range of monetary tools. The key feature of more recent approaches to measuring monetary conditions, therefore, has been to examine a wider range of variables, in order to capture information about tools such as quantitative easing (QE) and forward guidance, which aim to influence longer-term interest rates.

Conceptually, monetary conditions don’t include risky assets or private credit. This is because they do not fall within the category of variables relating to the conduct of monetary policy, as they are likely to be affected by credit risk premia. These would be relevant for measures of broader financial conditions.

It is important to stress that monetary conditions do not provide a direct reading of a central bank’s monetary stance. The monetary stance describes the impact of policy rate today, in combination with expectations of future policy actions, on real economic activity (February 2024 Monetary Policy Report). Monetary conditions are related to, and influenced by changes in the monetary stance, but by other factors too (such as household preferences for holding bank deposits).

Methodology

Our approach for constructing the UK MCI is similar to the data-driven approaches of Kucharčuková et al (2016) and Choi et al (2022). We estimate a Dynamic Factor Model (DFM) from a combination of the policy rate – which was constrained for a prolonged period by the effective lower bound (ELB) on nominal interest rates post-GFC – with a wider range of monetary and financial variables. We extract common factors driving comovement of the variables in our data set and construct a weighted average of these factors. Weights are equal to the proportion of overall variance that each factor explains, divided by its standard deviation.

This data-driven approach avoids imposing priors on the weights (eg relating the weights to the impact of individual variables on macroeconomic outcomes), which seems a natural benchmark.

We use monthly data since 1993, after the UK adopted inflation targeting. Our data set combines both price and quantity variables and includes three main variable categories.

First, interest rates. More specifically, Bank Rate; short-term overnight index swap rates (up to three years); and long-dated gilt yields (up to 20 years). We motivate the inclusion of interest rates across the yield curve as these are directly affected by policy rates and QE purchases, and likely to contain useful information on forward guidance.

Second, we follow Lombardi and Zhu (2018) by including monetary aggregates and central bank balance sheet variables to provide further information about monetary policy operations. Following Kiley (2020), these variables enter the DFM twice, as (log) levels and as year-on-year changes, to account for stock and flow effects respectively. It is debatable whether monetary aggregates and balance sheet variables provide material additional information about the real economy effects of monetary policy, over and above their impact on interest rates (see Busetto et al (2022) and Broadbent (2023)). Though this may risk double-counting, to the extent that our modelling strategy aims to let the data speak for itself, incorporating monetary aggregates and balance sheet variables provides useful information about their comovement with interest rates.

A key question is how to treat the exchange rate. Some MCIs retain the exchange rate to account explicitly for policy transmission via this channel. While they are part of the transmission of monetary policy, exchange rates are not seen as a policy instrument by the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC), and, importantly, are influenced by many domestic and global factors which may not be informative about UK monetary conditions (Forbes et al (2018)). On those grounds, we exclude the exchange rate. Sensitivity analysis suggests its inclusion did not materially change the empirical results.

Results

To give a sense of what is driving changes in the UK MCI, Table A summarises the estimated factor loadings from the DFM, as well as the weight of each factor in the UK MCI. The factor loadings reflect how the variables are weighted together within each factor, as well as the correlation between the variables and each factor. We assign a positive sign to Bank Rate across all factors, so that increases imply tighter monetary conditions; we expect a negative sign on monetary aggregates and central bank balance sheet variables, as an expansion in these quantities implies looser conditions.

Table A: Factor loadings

Notes: Factor loadings are averaged across different subcategories of variables.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

The factor loadings suggest that all blocks of variables have a significant bearing on the UK MCI. The first factor – which explains the largest share of common variance between the variables – is mainly driven by interest rates, the stock of monetary aggregates and balance sheet variables. By contrast, the rate of change of the quantity variables is the main driver of the second factor. We retain the first three factors, which explain almost 90% of overall variance in our data set.

Chart 1 plots the UK MCI in the bottom panel and some key input variables that feed into it. To interpret the UK MCI, note that it is normalised by subtracting its mean and dividing by its sample standard deviation. As such, we place less weight on the level of the UK MCI, and more on changes. As Batini and Turnbull (2000) highlight, you cannot make a statement about degrees of tightness, but you can make relative statements, such as whether monetary conditions are tightening or easing.

Chart 1: UK MCI and selected input variables

Notes: The index is expressed in standard deviations from average. Stalks denote: (I) GFC; (II) EU Referendum; (III) Covid-19; and (IV) start of tightening cycle. Latest observation: November 2023.

Sources: Bank of England, Bloomberg Finance L.P, Tradeweb and Bank calculations.

Our index points to a loosening in UK monetary conditions during previous stimulus episodes. The UK MCI drops significantly during the GFC (Chart 1, Stalk I), consistent with the MPC’s conventional and unconventional monetary policy actions. The UK MCI also suggests monetary conditions eased as a result of monetary policy actions following the EU Referendum (Stalk II) and Covid-19 (Stalk III), however less so than during the GFC.

During the recent tightening cycle (Stalk IV), the UK MCI increased slightly earlier than Bank Rate, reflecting the slowing pace of QE purchases in 2021. The tightening over 2021–23 was driven first by reduced balance sheet flows, and then moves in the yield curve, first at the short end, and then also at the longer end. The UK MCI also suggests that monetary conditions have loosened slightly since peaking in September 2023.

It is important to keep in mind that the UK MCI presented here is a statistical construct and reflects only one approach to measuring monetary conditions. Our modelling strategy is designed to weight together variables based on their historic comovement with each other, not their correlation with GDP or inflation. Due to our use of fixed weights, any state-contingent effects of policies are only indirectly captured in our index, to the extent that it is reflected in interest rates. That said, to the extent that monetary conditions transmit changes in the monetary stance to the real economy, it is plausible that our UK MCI provides some information about future macroeconomic outturns. Preliminary analysis is consistent with this view, though further research is required to substantiate the relationship between monetary conditions and the macroeconomy.

Conclusion

The UK MCI presented in this post provides a comprehensive new measure of UK monetary conditions, which synthesises information about both conventional and unconventional policies. Crucially, our measure shows material variation in the post-GFC period, when Bank Rate was constrained by the ELB. Indeed, it highlights that unconventional policy tools supported significant loosening in UK monetary conditions in response to the GFC and subsequent stimulus episodes. Even at times when the ELB is not binding, including the recent tightening cycle, the UK MCI provides more information about the evolution of monetary conditions, faced by economic agents, than a sole focus on Bank Rate would suggest.

Given that unconventional tools are now an established part of the monetary toolkit, further research into monetary conditions, and what they imply for macroeconomic outcomes, remains important.

Natalie Burr and Julian Reynolds work in the Banks External MPC Unit, and Mike Joyce works in the Bank’s Monetary and Financial Conditions Division.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk or leave a comment below.

Comments will only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

The transmission channels of geopolitical risk

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 04/04/2024 - 7:00pm in

Samuel Smith and Marco Pinchetti

Recent events in the Middle East, as well as Russia’s invasion of Ukraine, have sparked renewed interest in the consequences of geopolitical tensions for global economic developments. In this post, we argue that geopolitical risk (GPR) can transmit via two separate and intrinsically different channels: (i) a deflationary macro channel, and (ii) an inflationary energy channel. We then use a Bayesian vector autoregression (BVAR) framework to evaluate these channels empirically. Our estimates suggest that GPR shocks can place downward or upward pressure on advanced economy price levels depending on which of the two channels the shock propagates through.

The channels of GPR

To assess the effects of geopolitical tensions on the macroeconomy, it is first necessary to quantitatively measure GPR. Our approach to measuring GPR follows the work of Fed researchers Caldara and Iacoviello (2022), who develop an index GPR based on the number of articles covering adverse geopolitical events in major newspapers. This index reflects automated text-search results of the electronic archives of 10 major western newspapers. It is calculated by counting the number of articles related to adverse geopolitical events in each newspaper for each month (as a share of the total number of news articles).

Chart 1 shows the behaviour of the GPR index from 1990 to 2023. The index is relatively flat during large parts of the sample, and spikes around major episodes of geopolitical tension, such as the outbreak of the Gulf War, 9/11, the beginning of the Iraq invasion in the 2000s, and the Russian invasion of Ukraine in 2022.

Chart 1: The GPR index

Source: Caldara and Iacoviello (2022).

In the same paper, Caldara and Iacoviello (2022) show that on average, an increase in the GPR index is associated with lower economic activity, arguing that these effects are associated with a variety of macro channels, ranging from human and physical capital destruction, to higher military spending and increased precautionary behaviour.

However, episodes of geopolitical tension often involve increased concerns about the supply of energy to global markets. Chart 2 shows the cumulated percentage change in the three months ahead West Texas Intermediate (WTI) futures around key geopolitical events. Oil future prices rose following most of these episodes, potentially reflecting expectations of supply cuts to energy production or disruption of the flow of energy.

Chart 2: WTI futures three months ahead prices during the 30 days following major recent geopolitical events (associated with tensions on energy markets)

Source: Refinitiv Eikon.

This suggests that GPR can also transmit via an additional energy channel, whose effects are more akin to an adverse supply shock. Whether the shock transmits through this channel, and how strong it is relative to the macro channel, will depend on the wider context and/or location of the events relating to the shock. Disentangling the two effects is, therefore, important for correctly assessing the economic consequences of a GPR shock.

Measuring geopolitical surprises

We begin our analysis by constructing a series of exogenous surprises in (i) GPR, and (ii) oil prices that can be assumed to be entirely driven by geopolitical events to a reasonable degree of approximation.

In order to construct our surprise series, we adopt a selection of 43 main GPR events from 1986 to 2020 proposed by Caldara and Iacoviello (2022), which we update to include four important events that have occurred in the past three years: the escalation of the Afghanistan Crisis in August 2021; the Russian invasion of Ukraine in February 2022; the Istanbul bombings in November 2022; and the events in the Middle East in October 2023.

We compute the GPR surprise as the daily log difference in the GPR index around these events. For the oil price surprise, we compute the daily log difference in WTI future prices from one to six months ahead around the same dates. We then take the first principal component of these to capture movements in energy prices driven by the geopolitical shock.

Decomposing the macro and energy supply components of geopolitical surprises

We then use our event-study data set in a Bayesian-VAR setting for the euro area, the UK, and the US from January 1990 up to October 2023 to disentangle the effects of the macro uncertainty channel from the energy supply channel of GPR. We adopt the two-block VAR structure proposed by Jarociński and Karadi (2020), which uses high frequency data combined with narrative and sign restrictions to identify shocks.

Within the high-frequency block, we include our surprise series of (i) log changes in the GPR index in the main geopolitical event days, and (ii) the first principal component extracted from changes in WTI futures from one to six months ahead in the main geopolitical event days, both cumulated at monthly frequency in case of multiple events occurring in one month. Within this block, we impose the sign restrictions at the core of our identification strategy, which we outline in Table A.

We impose that the response associated with the macro channel drives upward surprises in the GPR index and negative surprises in the oil future curve during the first day the news is reported, as oil prices drop following a contraction in economic activity. Conversely, we impose that the response associated with the energy supply channel drives upward surprises in the GPR index jointly with positive surprises in the oil future curve during the first day the news is reported, as precautionary oil demand rises in response to concerns about future supply cuts or shipping disruption.

Table A: The sign restrictions associated with each channel of GPR

GPR MacroGPR EnergyGPR surprises++WTI surprises–+

In our monthly frequency block, we include the GPR index in logs, real Brent crude prices spot in logs, real natural gas spot prices in logs (as measured by the IMF benchmark), and the monetary-policy relevant price indices in levels (in deviation from their long-run trends, as is standard in the VAR literature).

Identifying two distinct channels of GPR

Chart 3 plots the response to a geopolitical shock that leads to a 100 basis points increase in the GPR index. The first row reports the responses of oil and natural gas prices to an ‘average’ geopolitical shock, which does not disentangle the effects of the macro and the energy channel, along the lines of Caldara and Iacoviello’s work. The second and the third rows display the responses when we assume that all of the increase in the GPR index propagates via just the macro channel and just the energy channel respectively.

Chart 3: Impulse response functions associated with an ‘average’ 100 basis points GPR shock, as opposed to a 100 basis points shock acting exclusively either through the macro or the energy channel­

In the ‘average’ case, the real Brent price spot rises by about 10% on impact, before then dropping of beyond 10% after around six months. However, these dynamics mask the two underlying channels. On the one hand, the energy supply channel is associated with a rapid 20% surge in the oil price. On the other, the macro channel is associated with a more gradual decline of beyond 20%.

The response of gas prices tends to be more persistent than oil prices: the effect of the energy channel on oil prices is concentrated in the first six months whilst the effect on gas prices wanes only during the second year after the shock.

The response of price levels across regions follows a pattern that is broadly consistent with energy price dynamics. As Chart 4 shows, inflation unambiguously drops in the ‘average’ case: the price level drops persistently by about 0.1% in the US, and shortly by about 0.25% in the euro area, while the response is not statistically significant for the UK. This finding is consistent with the interpretation of Caldara and Iacoviello (2022) of geopolitical shocks behaving, from an empirical perspective, as contractionary demand shocks.

However, this similarly masks the effects of the different underlying channels. On the one hand, the pure macro channel gives rise to a more pronounced drop in the median price level than in the case of the ‘average’ GPR shock, reaching -0.5% in the US and the UK, and -0.4% in the euro area. On the other hand, the response associated with the energy supply channel is inflationary, with the price level rising persistently by about 0.5% in the US, 0.7% in the UK, and 0.6% in the euro area.

Chart 4: Impulse response functions associated with an ‘average’ 100 basis points GPR shock, as opposed to a 100 basis points shock acting exclusively either through the macro or the energy channel

Summing up

This analysis highlighted the existence of two separate and intrinsically different transmission channels of GPR: (i) a deflationary macro channel, and (ii) an inflationary energy supply channel. Policymakers should be aware of these distinct channels: GPR shocks may propagate in different manners and require different responses.

Samuel Smith works in the Bank’s International Surveillance Division and Marco Pinchetti works in the Bank’s Global Analysis Division.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk or leave a comment below.

Comments will only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

Markup matters: monetary policy works through aspirations

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 28/03/2024 - 8:00pm in

Tim Willems and Rick van der Ploeg

Since the post-Covid rise in inflation has been accompanied by strong wage growth, interactions between wage and price-setters, each wishing to attain a certain markup, have regained prominence. In our recently published Staff Working Paper, we ask how monetary policy should be conducted amid, what has been referred to as, a ‘battle of the markups’. We find that countercyclicality in aspired price markups (‘sellers’ inflation’) calls for more dovish monetary policy. Empirically, we however find markups to be procyclical for most countries, in which case tighter monetary policy is the appropriate response to above-target inflation.

In a simplified setup where wages are firms’ only input cost, while consumers only buy domestically produced goods, the ‘battle of the markups’ takes an intuitive form (Rowthorn (1977)): 

  • Workers aspire to have their nominal wage W feature a certain excess, typically referred to as the ‘wage markup’ ({\mu_{w}} ) over the cost of their consumption basket P. This is equivalent to saying that their aspired real wage W/P equals {\mu_{w}} .
  • Firms aspire to set their price P to secure a price markup ‘{\mu_{p}} ’ over their marginal cost of production, which is the nominal wage rate W. That is: they aspire for P={\mu_{p}}W, implying that the real wage W/P desired by firms equal to 1/{\mu_{p}} .

By itself, there is nothing guaranteeing that real-wage aspirations held by workers and firms are mutually consistent in this framework – ie, there is nothing to ensure that {\mu_{w}} = 1/{\mu_{p}} (Blanchard (1986); Lorenzoni and Werning (2023)). Every time that workers get to reset their wage, they may consider the prevailing real wage too low, upping the nominal wage. When firms next get to reset prices, they may consider the current real wage too high, upping prices. This could give rise to unstable wage-price dynamics.

Unemployment as an equilibrating device

Layard and Nickell (1986) argued that the moderating effect from the presence of unemployment acts like a clearing mechanism. They posed that aspired markups {\mu_{p}} and {\mu_{w}} are likely cyclically sensitive. Workers might feel that they have less bargaining power when unemployment ‘u ’ is higher, making them settle for a lower wage markup. Unemployment can thus act to tame unrealistic aspirations. Formally, this can be captured by modelling the aspired wage markup {\mu_{w}}  as consisting of a structural component (‘\overline{\mu_{w}}’) alongside a cyclically sensitive one (‘-k_{w}\cdot u ’):

\mu_{w}(u)=\overline{\mu_{w}}-k_{w}\cdot u                                     (1)

Here, the structural component ‘\overline{\mu_{w}}’ captures workers’ aspirations based on ‘exogenous’ factors, eg what they have gotten used to given their past consumption patterns. If k_{w} > 0, the cyclical term ‘-k_{w}\cdot u ’ captures the notion that workers’ aspired markups are procyclical, so that workers are likely to ‘settle for less’ when the threat of unemployment is greater.

Similarly, price markups aspired by firms also consist of a structural component alongside a cyclically sensitive one:

\mu_{p}(u)=\overline{\mu_{p}}-k_{p}\cdot u                                       (2)

When it comes to the cyclicality of price markups, it is debated whether they are pro or countercyclical. On the one hand, a slowdown makes firms afraid of having to carry large inventories or suffer from capacity underutilisation. This would imply that aspired price markups are procyclical (k_{p} > 0). On the other hand, other theories imply that firms’ aspired markups move countercyclically (k_{p} < 0). For example, by pushing some firms out of business, a recession may increase the market power of surviving firms – implying that firms’ aspired markups rise in downturns.

In general, and irrespective of the sign of k_{p}, it is possible to find an equilibrium rate of unemployment, ensuring consistency between the real wage aspired by workers and that aspired by firms. At this point the wage-price cycle is put to rest – enabling inflation to land at target.

It can be shown that the equilibrium level of unemployment increases in structural aspirations held by workers and firms (\overline{\mu_{p}}+\overline{\mu_{w}}): when workers and/or firms aspire to obtain a greater size of the pie, without the pie having grown in size, something will have to give. Here, that is unemployment which has the effect of moderating the elevated aspirations, to re-establish consistency. If unemployment does not rise to tame aspirations, there will be pressure on inflation in the short run. This is what has been called conflict inflation.

The role of the central bank

The story so far assumes that, somehow, the unemployment rate ‘agrees’ to clear any conflict between firms and workers. In reality, it won’t automatically. There are many reasons for unemployment to exist, eg search frictions (Pissarides (2000)) or providing incentives to limit shirking (Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984)). This implies that the level of unemployment is not ‘free’ to clear any conflict and further action is required.

This is where the central bank comes in. Through its mandate, the central bank is tasked with setting policy to keep inflation at target. In our framework, this implies that the central bank will attempt to set its policy to ensure that cyclical conditions are such that markup aspirations are consistent with the size of national income. And if aspired markups are cyclically sensitive, there is an ‘aspirational channel’ of monetary policy transmission.

If aspired markups of both firms and workers are procyclical (k_{p}, k_{w} > 0), the policy prescription for the central bank is conventional: it should tighten in response to inflationary pressures, as doing so will lower aggregate markup aspirations – eventually re-establishing consistency, which brings inflation back to target.

There is however debate over the sign of k_{p} , with many studies arguing that firms’ aspired markups are, in fact, countercyclical (k_{p}<0), for example because more bankruptcies in recessions increase market power of surviving firms. Any resulting price increases can then be seen as a form of ‘sellers’ inflation’ (Weber and Wasner (2023)). In that case, policy prescriptions are less clear: even if a monetary tightening reduces workers’ aspired markups, it may not be successful in lowering inflation if the ensuing recession ends up increasing markups aspired by firms. On balance, inflation might thus increase following tighter monetary policy, and a more ‘dovish’ monetary policy would be called for – particularly if the channel via the Phillips curve (a monetary tightening lowering firms’ marginal costs) is weak. 

Consequently, it is important for central banks to know whether firms’ aspired markups are pro or countercyclical. We have estimated the cyclicality of the price markup (k_{p}) for 61 countries (details are in our Staff Working Paper), and find that price markups are procyclical in most, including the UK and the US, but countercyclical in various other countries (see Chart 1).

Chart 1: Estimated degree of cyclicality in price markups (k_{p} ) in various countries

Paying for imports

Recent UK experiences have been more involved than the stylised situation described thus far. Next to domestic workers and firms, foreign exporters also lay a claim on UK output – as output is partly produced with imports, like energy. As energy prices rose around Russia’s 2022 invasion of Ukraine, the UK’s terms-of-trade worsened and the share of national income flowing abroad suddenly went up – leaving less pie to be distributed domestically.

Absent any reduction in the structural components of markups aspired by firms and workers (\overline{\mu_{p}} and \overline{\mu_{w}}), a larger share of national income flowing abroad implies distributional conflict domestically – pushing inflation away from target. Since price markups are estimated to be procyclical in the UK (Chart 1), while the same is thought to apply to workers’ aspired wage markups, a rise in inflation may require the central bank to tighten. This is needed to moderate markup aspirations, ultimately clearing any conflict, enabling inflation to return to target.

Indeed, central bankers appear to have an ‘aspirational’ transmission mechanism in mind as can be seen from Christine Lagarde (2023):

We need to ensure that firms absorb rising labour costs in margins (…) The economy can achieve disinflation overall while real wages recover some of their losses. But this hinges on our policy dampening demand for some time so that firms cannot continue to display the pricing behaviour we have recently seen (emphasis added).

Conclusions and policy implications

A monetary tightening is not the only way via which markup aspirations could be moderated. Faced with an adverse terms-of-trade shock, it is also possible that workers and/or firms internalise the implications (that there is less income to be divided domestically), inducing them to lower the structural components of their aspired markups (\overline{\mu_{p}} and \overline{\mu_{w}}). In this regard, it would be interesting to obtain a better understanding as to whether communication (by central banks or governments) can ‘endogenise’ aspirations of workers and firms (making them directly sensitive to the terms-of-trade), as it is ultimately costly for a central bank to have to step in and tame aspired markups by affecting the business cycle.

Absent such a co-ordinated response, bringing inflation back to target following an adverse terms-of-trade shock may require a cyclical slowdown to moderate markups aspired by workers and firms. An important caveat is that this strategy might not work if firms’ aspired price markups are countercyclical, but we find no evidence for this in the UK. As a result, the monetary tightening implemented in recent years is likely to aid the disinflation process via our ‘aspirational channel’ (not present in most standard models, featuring acyclical desired markups), which facilitates inflation returning to target.

Tim Willems works in the Bank’s Structural Economics Division and Rick van der Ploeg is a Professor at the University of Oxford.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk or leave a comment below.

Comments will only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

Debt, Deficits, and Warranted Money

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Fri, 15/03/2024 - 12:49am in
by Brian Czech

chart showing the public and private debt levels of the six most indebted nations.

Concern over mushrooming debt is growing. Click on the image to see the casino-like tumbling of national debt “clocks.” (US Debt Clock)

If you recognize the damages done by a bloating economy, you’ll be alarmed by the global GDP meter, which hit the existentially menacing threshold of $100 trillion in 2022. If that doesn’t give you a dose of distress, try the global debt clock. Then, for a dizzying dose indeed, check the casino-like combination of debt and GDP maintained by “US Debt Clock.”

Almost all readers, bearish and bullish alike, can sense the unsustainability of skyrocketing debt. Even wild-eyed growthists, who see no problem in a perpetually growing GDP, can’t abide a perpetually growing debt. Yet very few critics of debt can articulate, with economic fundamentals, why such debt is so unsustainable.

Sadly absent from the discussion of debt is the ecological underpinnings of money. As long as these underpinnings remain overlooked, the money lenders will be overbooked. Deficit spending will rule the day, and global debt will continue rocketing into the stratosphere, heading for the sun like a pecuniary phoenix.

Let’s have a closer look at the debt problem, with a focus on global and U.S. scenarios. We’ll consider the relationship of debt to deficit spending, along with inflation. Finally, we’ll bring in the ecological basis of money, and hope our policymakers grasp and apply it, lest our money supply—not to mention the planet—turn to ashes.

Deficits and Debt: Global and U.S.

As global GDP was ramping up to the planetarily punishing $100 trillion level, global debt was already surpassing $300 trillion. It reached that dubious distinction in 2021, just one year after reaching the previous record of $226 trillion. It has since come down from the peak, but still stands around $238 billion, and the reduction is surely short-lived.

The majority of global debt is private, especially corporate but significantly household debt as well. Public debt—money owed by governments—makes up about a third.

In the USA, those proportions are roughly reversed. From the county commission to Capitol Hill, American politicians have ambitions that far exceed government coffers. When they’re not spending money to “stimulate the economy,” they’re trying to spend their way out of the social and environmental problems caused by an overstimulated economy. They spend money they don’t have; that’s deficit spending and it adds to the public debt.

Table showing revenue, expenditures, deficit, and debt for the U.S. government between 2022 and 2026.

Deficit spending is a way of political life in the U.S. Government. (Image snipped from 2024 Budget of the U.S. Government.)

At this point in fiscal year 2024 (October 1, 2023 through September 30, 2024), the U.S. government deficit stands at roughly $532 billion, contributing another two percent to the federal debt of $26 trillion. The deficit may lessen as taxes are collected in the coming months, but then it will shoot back up for the remainder of the year. Even the figures provided by the Administration (probably rosy figures) acknowledge that the deficit is expected to be a whopping $1.8 trillion by the end of fiscal 2024. That’s nearly seven percent of the 2023 GDP ($26 trillion).

The USA is particularly relevant to the global debt; its debt is bigger than any other. In fact, U.S. entities—government and private combined—carry a debt burden nearly the size of the global economy!

Only Japan and China have joined the USA in the club of over $10 trillion government debt. France, Italy, the UK, Germany, India, Canada, Spain, and Brazil all have debts exceeding a trillion dollars.

In terms of relative debt (ratio of debt to GDP), Japan is at the top of the list at 255 percent. Greece, Singapore, Italy, Bhutan, and the USA (123 percent) round out the top six.

Deficit Spending: Getting Dumb and Dumber?

Deficit spending has a long history in American policy. The fiscal exigencies of war have triggered deep deficits, with World War II as the classic case. But huge deficits were already incurred during the Great Depression, coinciding with the influence of the British economist John Maynard Keynes. In the General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, Keynes prescribed a liberal dose of deficit spending to spur the western economies out of recession.

But Keynes never said to go hog wild, much less stay that way. So, for many decades now Americans have heard the debate between fiscal conservatives and “deficit-spending liberals.” They both want growth, but conservatives think a persistent deficit and ballooning debt is more burden than boon for GDP. They typically only abide a big debt for hawkish military purposes. Otherwise they’re “budget hawks.”

official portrait of Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez

Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez, are you sure about MMT? (Wikipedia)

Inveterate deficit spenders, on the other hand, think they can stimulate the economy by picking the winners and funding the right programs.

Into this old debate comes “modern monetary theory,” centered around the idea that deficit spending is generally fine, and policymakers needn’t worry too much about a growing debt, as long as the economy is also growing. Beyond that, “MMT” seems to mean many things to many people and has polarized the economics community. Even pollyannish growthists like Paul Krugman find MMT “obviously indefensible.” Another growthist (aren’t they all?) at the dark-monied Mercatus Center calls MMT “a bizarre, illogical, convoluted way of thinking.”

MMT does, however, provide some political cover for politicians hunting pork. The late King of Pork, Senator Robert Byrd, would have championed MMT all the way to the bottom line. But MMT has persuaded some presumably more fiscally innocent members of Congress, most notably Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez, Senator Bernie Sanders, and even John Yarmuth, past chair of the House Budget Committee.

In any event, it’s hard to tell what’s so “modern” about MMT. It has a few new wrinkles—it picks them up as it goes along—but basically it’s just another phase of Keynesian thought on deficit spending. And, as President Nixon said a half century ago, “We’re all Keynesians now.” He could have added, “We’re all growthists, too!”

And so, the first subheading that appears in this year’s federal budget (page 5) is: “GROWING THE ECONOMY FROM THE BOTTOM UP AND MIDDLE OUT.” We could add: “WITH A SHOT OF DEFICIT STEROIDS.”

Money Supplies: Warranted vs. Inflated

In 1939, one Sir Roy Forbes Harrod wrote “An Essay in Dynamic Theory,” published in the stately Economic Journal. Until then, little had been theorized about the process of economic growth, and rarely with such nuance. Harrod’s approach is considered a leading precedent of growth theory.

Harrod spent much of his 20-page essay contemplating three kinds of growth rates: warranted, natural, and actual. Our charge here is not to dive deeply into Harrod’s thoughts on growth rates, but to see where they take us on debt and inflation. In particular, I propose we have three levels of money supply: warranted, real, and nominal.

Economists are familiar with the latter two. The real money supply has been adjusted for inflation, typically by pegging to a particular year. The nominal supply is expressed in terms of face value in real time. For example, $1.38 trillion today—the nominal money supply of a hypothetical country—is only one trillion real dollars, if we’re pegging to 2010.

It’s the “warranted” supply I’m proposing here. The concept stems from the trophic theory of money, which is that money originates via the agricultural surplus at the base of the economy. Not agricultural surplus in the sense of grain going to waste in the fields, but surplus in the sense that one farmer can grow enough to feed many people.

It is that surplus—more broadly, a food surplus but for all practical purposes the agricultural surplus—that frees the hands for the division of labor. The division of labor, in turn, allows for the exchanging of goods and services. All this calls for an efficient means of exchange, store of value, and unit of account: money, in other words.

Money is warranted, then, by the division of labor flowing from agricultural surplus.

Money didn’t just originate historically via agricultural surplus—as it did in Mesopotamia, Lydia, and the Yellow River Basin of China—it originates each year in the breadbaskets of the world. Actually it originates twice a year as these breadbaskets are found in Northern and Southern Hemispheres. North America (prairies and California), China, Southeast Asia, Brazil, and Chile come to mind, plus of course the contested confluence of political Europe and Russia, centered in Ukraine.

You might say money gets “printed” into circulation with each perennial pulse of wheat, rice, corn, oats, barley, and soybeans. Massive harvests free billions of hands for a spectacular division of labor and the exchanging of trillions of dollars of warranted money. Lenin was right on the money (so to speak) when he referred to grain as “the currency of currencies.”

Combine in a wheat field with a blue sky with clouds

Wheat combine “printing money” in North Dakota. (Flickr)

Think about it: How would money remain relevant in a world of agricultural collapse? Everyone would be occupied with growing, gathering, catching, or commandeering their own food. No one would be producing other types of goods and services, much less bringing them to market. Money would be worthless; it wouldn’t be warranted.

Not so with the collapse of massage services, NASCAR, hip hop, or even Taylor Swift. Nor with the disappearance of boats, guns, electronics, fur coats, or perfumes. A thousand container ships of manufactured dreck could be dumped in the Panama Canal, never to be seen or sold again, and the economy would persist. Plenty of other goods and services would remain. Money would still be meaningful, relevant, and valuable.

It’s an entirely different story with the world’s soy, root crops, poultry, livestock, finfish, and, above all, grain. Burn those up like some omnipotent, omnipresent Putin, and watch the economy come tumbling down in days.

That is why, in a fundamental sense, it is agricultural surplus that “prints” money into circulation. The warranted money supply, then, is that which reflects the amount of agricultural surplus. Lots of surplus warrants lots of money; little surplus warrants little money.

The trophic theory of money doesn’t explain every possible aspect of monetary economics, at least not directly. For example, how big a role do livestock and fish play in food surplus and therefore warranted money? What’s the linkage of food surplus to energy inputs? What about other natural resources at the trophic base of the economy such as heavy fiber and timber? (It takes clothing and shelter to subsist, not just food.)

The trophic theory of money generates plenty of research questions, but it provides plenty of insight as is. Take inflation, for example. That’s when the nominal money supply exceeds the warranted supply.

Limits to Warranted Money

While it is helpful to think of money as being “printed” into circulation with agricultural surplus, it is even more helpful to think of money being “footprinted” into circulation. There’s no way to produce an agricultural surplus—or a warranted money supply—without a heavy ecological footprint. Not for a population of eight billion people.

rows of green corn plant with a dark sky in the background

It takes a lot of inputs to grow a lot of food, so the ecological footprint of agriculture reaches far beyond the field. (Flickr)

Each parcel on the planet has a biological capacity. So, given limits to agricultural efficiency, we know that the ecological footprint of agriculture can only reach so far (or sink so deep, if you prefer). Then it exceeds the biological capacity, agricultural surplus plunges, and the warranted money supply drops like a shot.

The pre-existing, nominal money supply remains, but to what avail? With no agricultural surplus, businesses big and small disappear—banks, too—and the government defaults. All but the most civilized (or uncivilized but ethical?) polities descend into some sort of chaos. The nominal money supply might still be in the trillions of dollars, but it’s neither warranted nor real. It’s like the gold supply of King Midas. It’s hyperinflated, not because of an “overheated” economy and the pull of demand; quite the opposite. It’s devalued by “cost-push” inflation, the relentless price increases due to diminished stocks of natural capital.

What the Fed Needs Now

The Federal Reserve, U.S. Treasury, Budget Committee(s), World Bank, and all the other fiscal, monetary, and financial institutions need a reality check in the form of basic and applied ecology. They need to learn especially about the concepts of trophic levels and carrying capacity. Otherwise they won’t be able to sufficiently connect the dots among deficits, debt, and cost-push inflation.

Right now, the Fed’s approach to curbing inflation is the ham-handed raising of interest rates. But raising interest rates only works (sometimes) for the “demand-pull” form of inflation, where prices rise due to an increasing propensity to consume, or due to an injection of nominal money (as with deficit spending). It’s no remedy for cost-push inflation stemming from limits to growth in the real economy.

photo of the front of the Federal Reserve building

The Federal Reserve needs ecological training to manage inflation. (Wikipedia)

I’m not saying these accomplished folks—geniuses in other ways—have no sense of economic capacity. They most certainly do; they monitor and talk about it all the time. Unfortunately, they have essentially no knowledge of ecological capacity, so their notions of economic capacity are flawed. They tend to think of capacity in terms of financial capital, labor, manufacturing facilities, infrastructure, and new technology. It’s reminiscent of Herman Daly’s lament about focusing on the kitchen and the cook, with little thought to the ingredients.

When is the last time you heard a Jerome Powell or a Janet Yellen utter a word like “soil” or “water” or “forest” or “fishery”? Yet those are the stocks of natural capital at the very base—the trophic base—of the economy they preside over. They should be intent upon conserving those stocks, if not for purposes of long-term human wellbeing (which would be nice), then at least for purposes of fighting inflation!

Brian Czech is CASSE’s Executive Director.

The post Debt, Deficits, and Warranted Money appeared first on Center for the Advancement of the Steady State Economy.

Forecasting UK inflation in the presence of large global shocks

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 22/02/2024 - 8:00pm in

Dario Bonciani and Johannes Fischer

The UK economy has been hit by significant terms-of-trade shocks, most notably the rise in energy prices following the Russian invasion of Ukraine. These shocks have created substantial and persistent inflationary pressure in many countries. Such upheavals bring increased uncertainty about the future, making macroeconomic forecasting more challenging. In this post, we assess the forecasting performance of a state of the art empirical model, of the type commonly employed in academic research and policy institutions. This model is not used to produce the Monetary Policy Committee’s (MPC’s) forecast but has been used periodically within the Bank of England including as a cross-check to the main forecast. Specifically, we assess its performance in predicting UK inflation out of-sample at key dates around the start of the war in Ukraine. The model performs well in forecasting short-term inflation, but it struggles to fully capture inflation persistence over the longer term.

Methodology

To conduct our forecasting analysis, we have employed a Bayesian Vector Autoregressive (BVAR) model. These types of models have gained widespread popularity in academia and central banks for their flexibility and strong forecasting abilities, as evidenced by studies like Bańbura et al (2010) and Angelini et al (2019).

In essence, this empirical framework encompasses a series of linear equations designed to model the interdependencies and dynamics of macroeconomic variables. Further details on BVARs can be found here. Our specification includes 20 variables. Among these, 15 are specific to the UK economy, including the consumer prices index (CPI), real gross domestic product (GDP), the Bank Rate, and specific components of CPI, such as energy and food. Additionally, we incorporate global variables in the model, including world real GDP, global trade, and world CPI. Our model specification was used in a recent speech by Catherine L Mann, an external member of the Bank of England’s MPC. In her speech, she highlights how including periods of high inflation, such as 2022 Q1–2023 Q2, in the estimation sample affects the inflation forecasts of the BVAR.

The BVAR model relies on historical regularities between the included variables to produce forecasts. To capture these historical regularities, we estimate the model parameters using quarterly data from 1992 to 2019. To produce our BVAR forecasts, we make the additional assumption that the energy and food CPI components in the model are expected to follow exactly the same path as implied by real-time market futures curves (which will be influenced by financial market participants’ expectations about future prices). This assumption enables our model to factor in information about the latest events affecting food and energy prices. This assumption is necessary as we want the model to have all the information available at each point in time. Using the estimated historical regularities along with real-time information on the futures curves for energy and food prices, we then generate out-of-sample inflation forecasts at various points in time. In this post, we focus on the forecasts implied by the model before and after the onset of the Ukrainian conflict.

Empirical model estimated on pre-pandemic data

Chart 1 presents three panels illustrating inflation forecasts based on real-time data at two distinct time points: 31 January 2022 and 30 April 2022. The purple lines represent the BVAR forecasts, while the dashed lines depict the evolution of actual inflation. For comparison, we also include the median inflation forecast from the Market Participants Survey results as green dots. Finally, the shaded areas denote the statistical uncertainty surrounding the BVAR forecasts.

Chart 1: Comparing inflation forecasts at different points in time

In January 2022, as the threat of the Russian invasion became more likely, the BVAR forecast (upper Chart 1 panel) projected inflation to peak at 8% in November 2022. In comparison, professional forecasters expected inflation to peak at 6%, 2 percentage points lower than the BVAR.

Two months after the beginning of the Russian invasion, in April 2022 (lower Chart 1 panel), both the BVAR and professional forecasters had adjusted their forecasts upwards to reflect the increase in energy prices. In the short term (the first two quarters), the BVAR model closely tracked realised inflation. However, inflation proved more persistent than the model’s historical regularities and futures curves about food and energy prices could predict. The gap between the forecast of the BVAR and that of professional forecasters that existed in January disappeared almost completely by the end of April. One potential explanation for the initial difference in forecasts (and its disappearance) could be that professional forecasters had not considered the Russian invasion of Ukraine to be as likely as financial market participants had. Finally, professional forecasters also did not anticipate inflation remaining high for an extended period.

Overall, the BVAR model’s forecasts implied high rates of inflation before the Russian invasion of Ukraine but missed realised inflation by several percentage points. Once the Russian invasion had begun, the inflation peak of the BVAR forecast is close to the eventual peak.

Including post-pandemic information

Lastly, we examined whether the persistent rates of inflation seen over the past two years may significantly affect future BVAR forecasts, as argued in the above-mentioned speech by Catherine L Mann. To do so, we re-estimated the model with data that includes the run-up in inflation up until 30 April 2023, excluding the outlier data during the pandemic years (2020–21), as per the methodology in Cascaldi-Garcia (2022). The out-of-sample forecast with the data available at this point in time slightly increased the inflation persistence. Interestingly, over the full forecast horizon, the predictions from the BVAR model and professional forecasters aligned very closely.

Chart 2: Does post-pandemic data affect the inflation forecast?

Conclusion

Returning to our initial question, to what extent a linear model can predict inflation in the face of large terms-of-trade shocks. Prior to the war in Ukraine the model forecasted inflation significantly below its eventual realisation. This is not surprising because the model could not have foreseen the extent of the energy price increase associated with the war. Following the start of the war, when the energy price increase was realised, the BVAR model performed well in forecasting inflation in the nearer term despite its relative parsimony. However, it struggled to fully capture the inflation’s persistence over the longer term. Using data realisations from 2020 onwards to estimate the BVAR parameters can potentially help better capture the persistence of inflation in the future. Our analysis suggests that a linear model such as the BVAR can still prove to be robust for forecasting even in a turbulent macroeconomic environment.

Dario Bonciani and Johannes Fischer both work in the Bank’s Monetary Policy Outlook Division.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk or leave a comment below.

Comments will only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

CPI-weighted wage growth

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Wed, 14/02/2024 - 8:00pm in

Josh Martin

The Monetary Policy Committee has recently looked at wage growth as an important indicator of inflation persistence. One way that wages matter for price inflation is as a cost for businesses, who may raise their prices in response to higher wages. For this channel, the wage measure needs to reflect the coverage and composition of the Consumer Prices Index (CPI). However, most wage measures do not. This blog explores a wage growth measure which is re-weighted to better match the CPI.

What’s the link between wages and inflation?

There are at least two reasons to care about wages for inflation. First, wages are a source of income, which earners can then spend. So higher wages increase demand, putting upward pressure on prices. Second, wages are a cost to businesses. Higher wages increase business costs, who might raise their prices to maintain their profit margins.

In the first story, all labour income in the economy is relevant for inflation, since all workers earn and all workers can spend. A measure that reflects total labour income, including bonuses for instance, would be appropriate.

In the second story, only wages that produce items in the CPI basket matter for inflation. Higher wages in a firm which only produces exports are not relevant for CPI prices, since exports are not in the CPI. By contrast, wages in a firm which produces something for household consumption in the UK, like restaurant meals, are very relevant for CPI.

How to match wage data to the CPI

Most wage data, including the Average Weekly Earnings (AWE) published by the Office for National Statistics (ONS), is weighted by employment. That means it gives more importance (weight) to industries with more employees. This allows the statistics to measure the average (mean) wage growth of all employees in the economy, and within each industry.

To construct a wage measure that best reflects the composition of the CPI basket, we need to adjust the weights. We want to give more weight to industries which produce consumption products, and less to industries that produce things not in the CPI basket, like exports, government output, and investment goods. Since we are thinking about wages as a cost, we also want to give more weight to industries that are more labour-intensive, since wages will be a more important cost for those industries.

What about industries that produce intermediate goods and services, like raw materials or business services? Firms that make consumer products buy those things, so the wage costs might get passed along the supply chain and be relevant for CPI too. For instance, if an accountancy firm raises wages, and a restaurant buys accountancy services, then the higher accountancy wages might lead to more expensive restaurant meals.

That’s possible, but requires several steps – the accountancy raises wages, they must also raise their prices, the restaurant then must also raise its prices because of the higher accountancy costs. In reality, either accountancy firm or restaurant might not raise prices and instead accept a temporarily lower profit margin given higher costs. There are also likely long lags between accountancy wages and restaurant prices. So, given uncertainty and time lags, I won’t factor in the wages of industries that produce intermediate inputs, only those producing products directly sold to consumers.

To figure out the right weights for our CPI-weighted wage measure, I use data from the supply and use tables (part of the National Accounts) to spread the CPI weights to industries. First, I match the CPI weights to the detailed ‘product’ categories in the supply and use tables, spreading them out where necessary. I have to account for the difference in coverage of the CPI and household consumption in the National Accounts – for instance, the CPI excludes gambling, but the National Accounts includes it.

Second, I split apart the CPI weight for goods into that which reflects the good itself, and that which reflects the retail and wholesale services required to get the good to consumers. For instance, when you buy a banana in the shop, you are paying partly for the banana itself, partly for the wholesaler who got it to the UK, and partly for the retailer who put it on the shelf. Consumers don’t buy retail services directly, only indirectly through other goods, so retail doesn’t have an obvious weight in the CPI – it needs to be separated from the weight of goods.

Third, I account for which CPI products are imported and which are produced domestically. Consumers may buy lots of bananas, but if most of those are imported, then the wages in the domestic banana industry aren’t so important after all. Finally, I account for the share of wages in total costs of the industry. In industries that are more labour intensive, wages will be a more important cost, and so more relevant for the price.

Putting all of that together and the summing up by industry gives us a new set of industry weights for our wage measure. This should, in theory, better reflect the importance of each industry’s wages in the CPI.

Does the re-weighting make much difference?

Using these new weights to aggregate the industry AWE regular pay growth rates published by ONS gives a CPI-weighted wage measure. Chart 1 shows the annual growth in this measure between 2001 and 2023. The chart also shows the annual growth in AWE whole economy and private sector regular pay for comparison.

Chart 1: Measures of annual regular pay growth, January 2001 to December 2023

Source: ONS and author’s calculations.

Notes: Rolling three-month averages of annual growth. Latest period October–December 2023.

Over the long run there is little difference between the CPI-weighted AWE and the headline measures published by ONS. That suggests that the measures we usually look at do a good job of capturing the key information for understanding wages as costs for businesses. The new measure is just a re-weighted version of the same data underlying the other measures, so it is perhaps unsurprising that they are similar.

In the past year or so, there is a little more difference between the measures, as shown in Chart 2, which is the same data as in Chart 1 but zoomed in on the period since January 2019. The CPI-weighted AWE grew slower than the headline AWE measures during most of 2023. But in the past few months, while the headline measures have slowed sharply, the CPI-weighted measure has been flatter. That’s because the industries driving the fall in the headline measures include professional services and construction. These industries don’t produce many consumer products, so get much lower weights in the CPI-weighted AWE measure.

Chart 2: Measures of annual regular pay growth, January 2019 to December 2023

Source: ONS and author’s calculations.

Notes: Rolling three-month averages of annual growth. Latest period October–December 2023.

Chart 3 shows the difference between the industry weights in 2023 in the AWE private sector measure and the CPI-weighted AWE measure described in this blog. Green bars show industries with more weight in the CPI-weighted measure, such as wholesale and accommodation and food services. Industries that get less weight (shown in red) include professional services, construction, and admin services – all business-facing industries. Some of these industries would likely get a greater weight if also factoring in industries producing intermediate inputs for use in making consumer products.

Chart 3: Difference in weight between CPI-weighted wages and AWE private sector, 2023

Source: ONS and author’s calculations.

Notes: Industries are defined by SIC 2007, consistent with AWE breakdowns. Positive (green) bars show more weight in the CPI-weighted measure than AWE private sector, and negative (red) bars show less weight. Units are percentage points; for instance, accommodation and food services is weighted 12.7 percentage points higher (22.1% versus 9.4%).

Other people have also thought about this issue. Former MPC-member Silvana Tenreyro, in a speech in 2020, constructed a CPI-weighted measure of unit labour costs (labour costs per unit of output). This used National Accounts data on labour costs and productivity, so is slightly different to the measure in this blog, but done for the same reasons. She found that CPI-weighted unit labour costs were growing slower than whole economy unit labour costs between 2017 and 2019, mostly due to differences in productivity growth.

In a recent series of blogs, the White House Council of Economic Advisors constructed a wage measure to match the composition of core non-housing services inflation. They have far more detailed industry wage data available than we do in the UK. They suggest that this measure is a slightly better predictor of future core non-housing services inflation than other private sector wage measures.

Summing up

Overall, it seems like re-weighting wage data to match the CPI is a good idea in theory, but doesn’t make very much difference in practice, at least not so far. That might be because the available industry breakdown of wage growth from the AWE is quite limited, so there isn’t very much scope to pick out the key industries. But the re-weighting might be relevant in future. For instance, the increase in the National Minimum Wage in April 2024 will affect some industries more than others, and as we know, not all industries are equally important for CPI.

Correction (15 February 2024): This post has been corrected due to a calculation error in the weighting of the retail and wholesale industries. This principally affects Chart 3, though the other charts have also been updated. The author apologises for the error and any inconvenience caused.

Josh Martin works in the Bank’s External MPC Unit.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk or leave a comment below.

Comments will only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

Beyond the average: patterns in UK price data at the micro level

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Wed, 17/01/2024 - 8:00pm in

Lennart Brandt, Natalie Burr and Krisztian Gado

The Bank of England has a 2% annual inflation rate target in the ONS’ consumer prices index. But looking at its 700 item categories, we find that very few prices ever change by 2%. In fact, on a month-on-month basis, only about one fifth of prices change at all. Instead, we observe what economists call ‘sticky prices’: the price of an item will remain fixed for an extended amount of time and then adjust in one large step. We document the time-varying nature of stickiness by looking at the share of price changes and their distribution in the UK microdata. We find a visible discontinuity in price-setting in the first quarter of 2022, which has only partially unwound.

Theory of sticky prices and related literature

Understanding price-setting dynamics is essential for central banks. Most structural models in the literature use a form of time-dependent pricing, under which firms keep prices the same for fixed amounts of time (Taylor (1980)), or for random amounts of time such that there is uncertainty about the precise length of the price spell (Calvo (1983)). Another way of modelling sticky prices emphasises that firms will not just look at the time that has passed since they last adjusted its price, but also at how far their price is from some desired price level. This is called state-dependent pricing. Macroeconomic models don’t typically allow for time-variation in the degree of stickiness or switching between pricing strategies. Recently, however, firms in the Decision Maker Panel tell us that they have moved increasingly away from time-dependent towards state-dependent pricing. In this case, when there is a large shock affecting many firms, the shock leads to an increased frequency of price changes and so more immediate pass-through to overall inflation.

In order to better understand the pricing behaviour of firms in times of large inflationary shocks, we explore the pricing dynamics at the micro level using CPI microdata published by the ONS. We are of course not the only ones who have been interested in this type of data. Bank authors have been using this data set for a number of years. For example, Bunn and Ellis (2011) document stylised facts about pricing behaviour from the UK microdata and the August 2020 Monetary Policy Report used CPI microdata to inform policy. Elsewhere, Karadi et al (2020) use US microdata to analyse firms’ price-setting in response to changes in credit conditions and monetary policy. Nakamura et al (2018) analyse the societal cost of high inflation using microdata from the 1970s and 1980s, and Montag and Villar (2023) analyse the effect of more frequent price-changes on aggregate inflation during Covid. Relatedly, Davies (2021) finds that the difference between the share of price rises and price cuts in the UK microdata is related to aggregate inflation, focusing on price-setting during the pandemic. And finally, authors of the FT’s Alphaville blog have also been looking into these data (see here and here).

The data

The microdata spanning from 1996 until September 2023 is publicly available and updated monthly after each CPI release. It contains the monthly price quote data underpinning the ONS’ CPI series for over 700 items with identifiers at the shop, shop type, and region levels. We clean the data which works out to about 30 million observations. When identifying a price change in the data, which is ultimately what matters for inflation, we try to be as precise as possible with regards to the product and the timing of the change. To that end we only count the change if we find the same item, in the same region, in the same shop, in two exactly neighbouring months. For example, if a bag of potatoes cost £2 in January and £3 in March but was not recorded in February, rather than imputing a price we discard the observation since we cannot be sure in which month the change actually happened.

Stylised facts from the microdata

A brief look at the data lets us establish some stylised facts. Chart 1 shows a decomposition of these month-on-month price movements over all items in the data set. Four key observations stand out:

  1. Prices rise and fall all the time, but the vast majority of prices do not change between months. In any given month, on average since 1996, around 80% of prices remain unchanged relative to the previous month (blue line).
  2. The share of prices rising (in green) has increased notably since 2021 to an extent that has not happened in previous inflationary episodes in the sample (excluding VAT changes).
  3. The share of prices falling (in red) has fallen somewhat but remains stable since 2021, relative to historical average. The main margin of adjustment has been in the share of price increases.
  4. But, in recent months, while the share of prices rising has tapered off, it remains elevated relative to its historical average. 

Chart 1: Decomposition of price movements month-on-month

Notes: The share of prices rising and falling reflect month-on-month changes. Shares are seasonally adjusted using the R package seasonal. Spikes in 2008, 2010 and 2011 are a consequence of UK VAT changes (17.5% to 15% in 2008, increase to 17.5% in 2010 and increase to 20% in 2011). The grey shaded area covers the time between March 2020 and July 2021 when the economy (and data collection) was most affected by the Covid pandemic. Dashed lines show the 2011–19 averages. Latest observation: September 2023.

Sources: ONS and authors’ calculations.

To be clear, this chart is not saying that 80% of products never change prices. If the price of an item remained constant between December and January, and rose between January and February, it would move from the blue into the green category during this period. Similarly, it would fall out of the green, into the blue or red, if from February to March the price again remained constant, or fell, respectively.

So, perhaps surprisingly, this chart shows that monthly price dynamics in the economy are driven by only a relatively small fraction of roughly 20% of all goods and services in the consumption basket. Also, we see that in the most recent episode, the shift into rising prices has been mostly out of the ‘no change’ category. Hence, fewer prices are staying fixed, and more are rising. It is worth noting that the recent up-tick in the shares of prices rising is only matched historically by those caused by VAT changes in 2008, 2010 and 2011, which however appear as one-off price spikes rather than a persistently higher share of price rises, as in 2022.

If it is a minority of total products whose price changes, it is important to take a closer look. Chart 2 shows the distribution of prices changes from 2019 by quarter (truncated at zero to exclude no-change observations). In line with the rise in the green line in Chart 1, we observe that over 2021 and 2022 a lot of mass moved into the right side of the distribution, that is the share of price increases, with the share of price decreases being relatively stable.

Chart 2: Evolution of the distribution of price changes by quarter 2019–23

Notes: The share of prices that did not change is excluded from these densities. The truncated densities are estimated in R via the Bounded Density Estimation package using the boundary kernel estimator. Darker colours correspond to quarters in which year-on-year CPI inflation was relatively high, lighter colours to quarters in which it was low. Each distribution represents month-on-month changes within the same quarter. Latest observation: 2023 Q3.

Sources: ONS and authors’ calculations.

A note on the chart: the distribution of price changes, when aggregate inflation is at or close to target, is roughly symmetric in logarithms. On this scale, a doubling (+100%) is equally far away from zero as a halving of the price (-50%). Due to sales, the doubling and halving of prices actually happens regularly in the data, which explains the bunching around these points. While these may be a source of seasonality in the data, which may obscure the underlying dynamics, we do not believe they are important for the overall shape of the distribution which we show here.

In Chart 3, we zoom in on a couple of these densities to better see differences in their shape. They are the densities corresponding to price changes in the third quarter of 2022 and 2023 alongside an average density over the pre-Covid period.

Chart 3: Comparison of densities from 2022 and 2023 against a pre-Covid average

Notes: The share of prices that did not change is excluded from these densities. The truncated densities are estimated in R via the Bounded Density Estimation package using the boundary kernel estimator. To compare densities across time, they are normalised to sum to the average share of prices falling and rising respectively within the quarter. The yellow line shows the pointwise average density over the third quarters of the years 2011–19.

Sources: ONS and authors’ calculations.

We can see how, compared to this historical average – which we use as a stand-in for pricing behaviour when inflation was close to the 2% inflation target – 2022 saw a huge number of prices increase while there was little change in the behaviour of the lower part of the distribution. In the latest data, this mass of increases has begun to subside, and, at the same time, there is a growing number of prices outright falling on the month. However, the modal price increase (that is, the most probable) is still elevated at about 6%, compared to roughly 3% on average during 2011–19).

Conclusion

To summarise, looking at the micro level of price changes, we find a visible discontinuity in price-setting in the first quarter of 2022. A variety of factors, such as the large rise in energy prices in early 2022, as well as supply-chain issues following Covid lockdowns, likely contributed to this significant change in price-setting dynamics in the UK (relative to any recent historical precedent at least). At the micro level, firms’ pricing decisions led to the emergence of a large rebalancing in the distribution of price changes. Suddenly, more prices for many different products were rising at the same time. Compared to the available history for these data, the recent period is unique. More research will be needed on the causes of this marked shift in the distribution of price changes, both at a micro and at a macro level.

In the very latest data, there is some evidence that the distribution of price changes has indeed begun to return in the direction of its historical average, though it is too soon to establish a trend.

Lennart Brandt and Natalie Burr work in the Bank’s External MPC Unit, and Krisztian Gado is a PhD candidate at Brandeis University.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk or leave a comment below.

Comments will only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

Top 5 posts 2023

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 21/12/2023 - 8:00pm in

Rebecca Freeman

As another year draws to an end and the blog prepares for some downtime over the festive period, we wanted to take a look back at the blog in 2023.

In case you missed any of our posts the first time round, the five most viewed posts for the year were:

  1. How house prices respond to interest rates depends on where they are in the country
  2. Why lower house prices could lead to higher mortgage rates
  3. Bomadland: How the Bank of Mum and Dad helps kids buy homes
  4. ‘There is all the difference in the world between paying and being paid’: margin calls and liquidity demand in volatile commodity markets
  5. Location, location, location? How UK housing preferences shifted during the pandemic

We hope you enjoyed the blog in 2023. Happy New Year and we look forward to you reading our posts in 2024!

Rebecca Freeman, Managing Editor

Wages and Inflation: Let Workers Alone

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Wed, 20/12/2023 - 8:32pm in

[Note: this is a slightly edited ChatGPT translation of an article for the Italian daily Domani]

Last week’s piece of news is the gap that opened between the US central bank, the Fed, and the European and British central banks. Apparently, the three institutions have adopted the same strategy, deciding to leave interest rates unchanged, in the face of falling inflation and a slowdown in the economy. But, for central banks, what you say is just as important as what you do; and while the Fed has announced that in the coming months (barring surprises, of course) it will begin to loosen the reins, reducing its interest rate, the Bank of England and the ECB have refused to announce cuts anytime soon.

To understand why the ECB remains hawkish, one can read  the interview with  the Financial Times  of the governor of the Central Bank of Belgium, Pierre Wunsch, one of the hardliners within the ECB Council. Wunsch argues that, while inflation data is good (it is also worth noting that, as many have been saying for months, inflation continues to fall faster than forecasters expect), wage dynamics are a cause for concern. In the Eurozone, in fact, these rose by 5.3% in the third quarter of 2023, the highest pace in the last ten years. The Belgian Governor mentions the risk that this increase in wages will weigh on the costs of companies, inducing them to raise prices and triggering further wage demands; As long as wage growth is not under control, Wunsch concludes, the brakes must be kept on. Once again, the restrictive stance is justified by the risk of a price-wage spiral, that so far never materialized, despite having been evoked by the partisans of rate increases since 2021. Those who, like Wunsch, fear the wage-price spiral, cite the experience of the 1970s, when the wage surge had effectively fueled progressively out-of-control inflation. The comparison seems apt at first glance, given that in both cases it was an external shock (energy) that triggered the price increase. But, in fact, it was not necessary to wait for inflation to fall to understand that the risk of a wage-price spiral was overestimated and used by many as an instrument. Compared to the 1970s, in fact, many things have changed. I talk about this in detail  in Oltre le Banche Centrali, recently published by Luiss University Press (in Italian): Automatic indexation mechanisms have been abolished, the bargaining power of trade unions has greatly diminished and, in general, the precarization of work has reduced the ability of workers to carry out their demands. For these and other reasons, the correlation between prices and wages has been greatly reduced over three decades.

But the 1970s are actually the exception, not the norm. A recent study by researchers at the International Monetary Fund looks at historical experience and shows that, in the past, inflationary flare-ups have generally been followed with a delay by wages. These tend to change more slowly than prices, so that an increase in inflation is not followed by an immediate adjustment in wages and initially there is a reduction in the real wage (the wage adjusted for the cost of living). When, in the medium term, wages finally catch up with prices, the real wage returns to the equilibrium level, aligned with productivity growth. If the same thing were to happen at this juncture, the IMF researchers believe, we should not only expect, but actually hope for nominal wage growth to continue to be strong for some time in the future, now that inflation has returned to reasonable levels: looking at the data published by Eurostat, we observe that for the eurozone, prices increased by 18.5% from the third quarter of 2020 to the third quarter of 2023,  while wage growth stopped at 10.5%. Real wages, therefore, the measure of purchasing power, fell by 8.2%. Italy stands out: it has seen a similar evolution of prices (+18.9%), but an almost stagnation of wages (+5.8%), with the result that purchasing power has collapsed by 13%.

Things are worse than these numbers show. First, for convergence to be considered accomplished, real wages will have to increase beyond the 2021 levels. In countries where productivity has grown in recent years, the new equilibrium level of real wages will be higher. Second, even when wages have realigned with productivity growth, there will remain a gap to fill. During the current transition period, when real wages are below the equilibrium level, workers are enduring a loss of income that will not be compensated for (unless the real wage grows more than productivity for some time). From this point of view, therefore, it is important not only that the gap between prices and wages is closed, but that this happens as quickly as possible.

In short, contrary to what many (more or less in good faith) claim, the fact that at the moment wages are growing more than prices is not the beginning of a dangerous wage-price spiral and the indicator of a return of inflation; rather, it is the foreseeable second phase of a process of rebalancing that, as the IMF researchers point out, is not only normal but also necessary.

The conclusion deserves to be emphasized as clearly as possible: if the ECB or national governments tried to limit wage growth with restrictive policies, they would not only act against the interests of those who paid the highest price for the inflationary shock. But, in a self-defeating way, they would prevent the adjustment from being completed and delay putting once and for all the inflationary shock behind us.

Pages