Interviews

Error message

  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Deprecated function: The each() function is deprecated. This message will be suppressed on further calls in _menu_load_objects() (line 579 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/menu.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Deprecated function: implode(): Passing glue string after array is deprecated. Swap the parameters in drupal_get_feeds() (line 394 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).

Credit the Economic Planner

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 18/01/2024 - 11:42pm in

Tags 

Interviews

HAIPHONG:Welcome, everyone. Welcome to the stream. It’s Danny Haiphong, your host. As you can see, I’m joined by the renowned economist and author, Professor Michael Hudson. You can find his website in the video description. Please do hit the like button as we begin. That helps boost this stream. And, of course, you can find not only Michael’s website, but all the ways you can support this channel in the video description. How are you doing today, Michael? 

HUDSON:Pretty good. It’s snowing here in New York, so I’m pretty much snowed in. 

HAIPHONG:Yep. Yes, yes, it is quite bad out there today. But I am glad to have you here because there’s a lot of economic news. But you emphasize, and this channel tries to emphasize, the relationship between geopolitics and economics, geopolitical economy, as you, Radhika [Desai], and Ben Norton, and other great journalists have attempted to do. 

And so I wanted to start, then, let’s talk about Ukraine first. Let’s begin there. There’s all kinds of talks about there being a quote-unquote stalemate with regard to Ukraine. 

However, the realities, especially economically and on the battlefield, are a lot different. So, Michael, I’m just going to let you go on what you would like to comment on with regard to Ukraine, because the situation is not as hot in the news, but there are massive changes happening in this conflict. 

HUDSON:Well, it’s the United States that’s saying that it’s a stalemate in Ukraine. What they mean is that the Ukraine counter-offenses have been utterly ineffective. Ukraine has lost the war. 

And there have been almost all of the discussions that you get, for instance, on Judge Napolitano’s interviews, and the European press, the Russian press, the Chinese press, they all say, Well, the war is over. Russia can just continue to take however much it wants, but there is no point in Russia trying to take more land right now because Ukraine, or rather Mr. Zelensky, is sending all of the Ukrainians he can find, especially the Hungarian Ukrainians, the Russian-speaking Ukrainians, and the Romanian Ukrainians, in the fight to get killed. 

So, maybe we can convince Russia, Don’t mop up, don’t lock in your victory. Why don’t we just say it’s a stalemate and leave things the way they are since you’re winning so strongly? 

Well, obviously, Russia has already said, We’ve already given the terms for our peace. Of course, we can negotiate anytime. Our terms are simple, total surrender. We’re going to get rid of Nazism. We’re going to make sure that Ukraine will never join NATO. And we’re going to make sure that the Russian speakers and Crimea are part of Russia. So anytime you want to negotiate, meaning, say yes to our terms, we’ll be glad to. But meanwhile, we’re just going to sit here. And if you want to send more and more troops in, that’s fine. 

Now, the Americans think that, okay, if Russia isn’t taking any more land, it’s a tie. But it’s really not a tie because if you read President Putin’s speeches and Foreign Secretary Lavrov’s speeches, he says, Well, Ukraine is only the tip of the iceberg. We’re talking about the big picture. The big picture is, for instance, that Russia on January 1st became the lead administrator of the BRICS+. 

And the United States is meanwhile losing the fight all over the world. It’s losing the economic fight against Russia and China. Russia is increasing its industrial production, not only military, but in the production of aircraft, automobiles. China is growing and the United States is not. And most of all, Europe is going into a depression led by the collapse of, or I should say, the destruction of German industry as a result of the sanctions against Russia. And also the sanctions that the United States are insisting that Europe impose against China. 

The United States has told Europe, you really can only trade with us and our NATO allies. 

We want you to reduce your trade with China to what the head of the EU, Mr. Borrell, has said. He said, Well, you know, China, we import a lot more from you than we export. It’s got to be even. And China said, well, there are plenty of things we’d like to import from you, Europeans, such as the chip-making etching machinery for ultraviolet etching that’s made by Holland. And Borrell says, Oh, we can’t, the United States won’t let us send you, sell you anything that potentially is used in the military. And China says, well, anything that can be used economically can be military because the military is part of the economy. 

So I guess we’re quite happy to agree with you and have balanced trade between China and Europe. We’ll just cut back our trade with you to maybe the $100 a year trade that you have to trade with us. 

So Europe is voluntarily isolating, limiting its trade and investment to the United States, cutting off the trade with Russia. And without Russian gas and oil, you’re going to have the German, French, and Italian manufacturing industry, chemical industry, fertilizer industry, and agriculture continue to shrink. 

And so the stalemate that America is talking about really means we’re shrinking our allies in Europe. We’re losing the third world. And what is happening in Ukraine, fighting to the last Ukrainian, now looks like a similar fight in the Near East, where it looks like there’s a similar stalemate, which really has been inflaming the world’s global majority and the global South into thinking that all of a sudden this is something awful. I’ll get to that later. 

But the important thing is that I think the Americans have already realized that they’re going to lose the war in Ukraine. And the problem, as you read the New York Times and the Washington Post, and especially the Financial Times, is if we lose the war in Ukraine, how will Biden win the election in November? Because he’s been pushing, his whole policy is we can essentially wreck Russia. Our sanctions are going to lead to the collapse of Russian industry. The Russian people will get so upset with the war, there’s going to be a regime change. They’ll overthrow Mr. Putin and we can get another Boris Yeltsin in who is going to really wreck Russia in the way that our neoliberal advisors were able to wreck it in the 1990s. 

Well, that hasn’t happened. So what’s going to happen? Well, the public relations people of the Democratic Party have got together and they’ve all decided, Okay, what we want to tell the people is, it really didn’t matter in Ukraine. It doesn’t matter because we don’t have to win in Ukraine because America can fight [with] a kind of soft power. And we have other ways of dominating the world and maintaining America number one, even though we’re de-industrializing our economy. Even though we’re the largest debtor in the world, we’re going to be able to dominate. And the new Democratic Party public relations push is what’s called “soft power”. 

And in yesterday’s January 15th Financial Times, there was a long discussion. They had a whole page by a man who had been President Clinton’s advisor, National Intelligence Council advisor Joseph Nye. For a whole page. And it was Nye who coined the term soft power. A few decades ago, when he was arguing with Paul Kennedy, who was saying that the Americans were on the decline. And he came up with this idea to say, the United States can still be able to exert influence, but not of a military type, but of financial power, regime change. 

And what he said, he gave five reasons why the United States would not necessarily be eclipsed by China or by Russia or by any other countries. And it’s hilarious to look at the five reasons that the Financial Times yesterday trotted forth for why there’s not going to be any threat to the United States. 

The first reason he gave was geography and friendly neighbors. Well in the last few months, especially since the fighting and Israeli attacks on Gaza have occurred, America’s lost public opinion. And even Secretary Blinken has said that the fight in Israel is creating antagonism, not only against Israel, but America has lost its moral dominance as a result of backing the genocide and opposing any criticism of Israel within the United Nations. So it’s lost foreign support. There’s a growing anti-Americanism, not only in Asia, Africa, and the global South, but in Europe. 

Well, the second reason that Nye cited was domestic energy supplies. America controls oil. Not only does it produce its own oil, but it’s just been able to block the rest of the world from importing Russian oil, and it’s been able to blow up Nord Stream. And now it’s pushing Israel to essentially act as another Ukraine. It’s pushing Israel to incite Lebanon and Iran into a provocation, into a military response to the Israeli attacks that is going to enable Israel to do what a Senate majority leader, the Republican leader, has been pushing for, and what Biden is pushing for, and what the neocons have been pushing for for 20 years, war with Iran to grab the oil reserves of what were Iran, Syria, Iraq, and Libya.

If it can control the oil reserves of the Near East and be able to block off their energy exports to all the other countries, just as it’s been able to block Russia’s oil exports to Europe, then it can control the industrialization of other countries because industry basically runs on oil and gas. Industry is energy, and without energy, you’re not going to be able to have your own industrialization independently of the United States. So the U.S. foreign policy, as we’ve talked before, I think, in our last show, for 100 years, the United States has used oil as an attempt to control the world’s economy. 

Well, the third point that Nye points out is the dollar-based financial system. Well, it’s amazing that he could say that in yesterday’s Financial Times when the whole world was trying to de-dollarize. You’re getting one speech after another, not only from Russia and from China, but from the global South countries. And even in the Near East, they’re saying now that America has grabbed Russia’s foreign exchange reserves, $300 billion, all of the money that we’ve saved in our domestic monetary reserves are subject to confiscation by the United States. And they’ve already told Saudi Arabia that if they do not keep their international reserves from oil exports in the form of United States stocks and bonds, that would be treated as an act of war. So here in the Near East, you’re having Saudi Arabia and Bahrain under increasing pressure to support the Arabs being attacked by Israel, and yet they’re afraid to act because the United States is holding their dollars hostage. Well, very quickly, you’re seeing other countries move out of dollars as quickly as they can. 

And finally, the fifth argument that Nye points out for why America cannot lose is demo-graphic and technological leadership. But that’s the one fatal Achilles heel of the United States economy. Its hope, its idea of technological leadership is to get monopoly power over information technology, pharmaceuticals, and other areas that it can dominate for intellectual property through copyrighting and through essentially suing countries that will adopt the technology that’s developed in the United States. 

Prof. Hudson steps away for a minute. 

HAIPHONG:That summary, Joseph Nye outlined it, and Professor Hudson broke it down, broke down the facade, or the reality behind the facade that the neocons spread. And what’s so interesting about this piece is that, I mean, Joseph Nye, I mean, he is a Carter and then 

Clinton functionary, someone who served as an Undersecretary of State and Undersecretary of Defense for these administrations. And he is someone who actually has been considered less hawkish, but if we went through this article, you would see that what he is arguing with regard to soft power is actually regime change by other means. 

And that regime change is heavily connected to the economic realm, as perhaps Professor Hudson outlined so eloquently. There is so many connections to be made. We have a lot of them I’m going to raise with Professor Hudson, including on Russia, Russia being now the biggest economy in Europe by purchasing power parity terms. 

Also, the China collapse theory. There’s new news. There’s recent news about China actually surpassing Japan and leading the world now in car manufacturing and how its electric vehicle production is causing so much alarm. 

Prof. Hudson returns

I wanted to now ask you about a development, given all that you outlined with regard to Joseph Nye’s assessment and analysis on soft power in the US’s so-called advantages. I wanted to talk to you about this story here. Vladimir Putin was just meeting with business leaders in the Far East, and he made a claim about Russia now being the biggest economy in Europe by purchasing power parity (PPP) terms, becoming Europe’s first economy, despite pressure from all sides. 

And here’s what he said. He said, It seems that we are being strangled and pressured from every side, but still we are the largest economy in Europe. We left Germany behind and climbed into fifth in the world. China, the U.S., India, Japan and Russia. We are number one in Europe. And so there’s reports in that conversation with business leaders from the region that Russia is set to grow three percent year on year, and it’s likely to be even higher, maybe four and five percent. 

Now, there’s also the news, you brought it up, but there is a huge stagnation going on in Europe. In an analysis also in Financial Times, there are 48 economists that talked about the eurozone set for weak growth this coming year. And the prediction was across these economists, zero point six percent on average, with many indicating less than that. And of course, some indicating more. But the vast majority said it was going to be less than half of one percent. So, Michael, your thoughts. How did this, how did this happen? And perhaps you can explain the economic intricacies on how this happened. 

HUDSON:Well, we’ve discussed in the past how it happened. The United States, starting with President Clinton and actually with President Carter, decided to help American firms make higher profits by moving their labor force out of the United States, by trying to shift manufacturing first to Mexico, along the maquiladoras  under Carter, and then under Clinton to China and Asia. 

And the idea was to create increasing industrial unemployment in the United States to prevent labor’s wages from rising. And the theory that has guided the Democratic Party’s economists is, if you can cut wages, there will be higher profits and higher profits will lead to more prosperity. 

Well, the reality is that you cut wages by moving your industry outside of the country, by de-industrializing. And that is still the policy that America has taken. And it has replaced industrialization with financialization to make money financially, hoping that the companies that have now moved out towards China and Asia and other countries are going to be able to have higher profits and essentially become more prosperous for the donor class to the Democratic and also the Republican parties. 

But what President Putin was talking about was something much more. Russia already, along with China, have begun to produce their own airplanes. Take a look at the last week’s news, all about Boeing, yet again, having other accidents on its airplanes. Boeing used to be a technological leader in aircraft, but then it was merged with McDonnell Douglas and became a financial company. So it broke up the Boeing system of making airplanes and began to outsource to various other companies, all the little parts. And all Boeing is now is assembling diverse parts that it buys from various suppliers, very much like television sets are made. You buy different parts from different suppliers. 

Well, the reason Putin is making his speech in the Near East is Russia and China are working together for an enormous industrial development to take place in eastern Siberia, which has been obviously underpopulated because of the bad weather for many centuries now, but also is now beginning to warm up. And the idea is to integrate Chinese industry and Russian industry and technology and to design entire cities that are going to be technological complexes producing all sorts of interrelated parts together, computer parts, airplanes, trains, automobiles. China is already the largest automobile exporter in the world. And so you’re going to have this whole new center of industrial growth in eastern Asia. 

Well, the idea is that this is going to be a great increase in prosperity. And the way in which these cities are developing, when I first went to Russia in 1994, I stayed at the home of the professor who had designed Togliatti City, the city where they were going to begin producing automobiles designed by the Italians. And he explained how he designed the whole city together to combine the factories and production to workers’ housing, to workers’ entertainment, to workers’ health, and all of the different forms of supplying materials and parts of cars all dovetailed together. Well, he was basically an industrial engineer. And that is how Russia and China are developing the cities that they’re creating along with universities, training systems in East Asia and Siberia. 

So essentially, Putin is saying to the world, if you’re a global south country or an Arab country, and you want to have your economy grow and trade more, who are you going to tie your economy to? The world is being split into two parts, the US-NATO “garden” and the rest of the world, 85% jungle. The jungle is growing. The garden isn’t growing because its philosophy is not industrialization. Its philosophy is to make monopoly rents, meaning rents that you make in your sleep without producing value. You just have a privilege of a right to collect money on a monopoly technology that you have. 

But China and Russia are way ahead of the United States in most of the growth technologies that we’re talking about, not yet in the ultraviolet etching of computer chips, but in many areas. 

So you’re having the whole shift of technological advance move away from North America and the United States, where it was ever since World War I, to Russia and China. 

How is the United States going to cope with the rest of the world industrializing and not needing any contact with the United States? 

President Biden keeps saying China is our enemy. Ultimately, our military says we’re going to have war with China within two or three years. We’re at war with Russia right now in the Ukraine. That’s our objective, war. 

But the rest of the world, essentially, its response is not a mirror image of this, is not to say, well, we can go to war. We’re going to have Russia fighting Europe. 

Just in the last few days, you had numerous American military magazines and especially European spokesmen saying, if we lose in Ukraine, Russia is going to march right through Poland and Romania, right to retake Germany. It’s going to conquer Europe, and maybe it won’t even stop in England. 

Well, that’s just nonsense. The reality is that Russia and China don’t need Europe anymore. 

They don’t need the United States. Whereas under the Clinton administration, Madeleine Albright said, America is the unique country. It’s the necessary country. 

The fact is that the rest of the world not only finds America unnecessary, but America and its NATO allies to be the major threat to their own prosperity. So they’re essentially splitting into their own world. And the BRICS group is expanding its trade relations, its investment relations, and especially its financial clearing and monetary operations to be independent of the dollar, de-dollarizing, and certainly independent of the euro, which seems to have no visible means of support right now, and going their own way. 

Now, that is exactly what has led the United States to push Israel [essentially] to follow Netanyahu’s belligerence, because the United States says, We realize we’re losing power. 

We know that it’s really not a stalemate. We know that we’ve lost the chance for world dominance. We may be re-elected by telling people, you know, it doesn’t really matter. 

But we know that it does matter. The last chance we have to assert American power is military. And the main military prize is the Near East now, just as it was after 9-11, when Dick Cheney and Rumsfeld pressed for an invasion of Iraq to begin grabbing its soil and to essentially create America’s foreign legion in the form of ISIS and al-Qaeda Iraq. So now America has two armies that it’s using to fight in the Near East, the ISIS/al-Qaeda foreign legion (Arabic-speaking foreign legion) and the Israelis. The plan is—and America is willing to fight to the last Israeli, just as it’s willing—it’s trying to fight to the last Ukrainian in order to make this final grab of the Near East in fighting Iran. 

This is a crazy idea, but it seems that that’s exactly what is being planned. 

General Petraeus, who lost the war in Afghanistan, has said, we’ve got to conquer Iran. That’s going to be—we can regain all the power that we’ve lost by attacking Iran. And so now it looks like President Biden is hoping to make a political comeback by saying, Well, we may not have blocked Russia and Ukraine, but at least we’ve conquered the Near East. 

But the way in which it’s conquering it [somehow has] become a catalyst to make the whole global majority, the whole rest of the world, especially Africa, South America, and South Asia, to think, Wait a minute, what’s happening in Israel and Palestine today is exactly what happened to us at our beginning. 

In the United States, what did the Americans do? The White people came, the Anglo-Saxons and the other Europeans, and they killed 90% of the Indians, drove them out, isolated them, put them in basically concentration camps. And then when they found out that there was oil under these concentration camps, they essentially murdered the Indians there or drove them out to grab the oil. 

Same thing in Latin America. When the Spaniards came to Latin America, they grabbed the land, drew up land grants, and these land grants created latifundia, which has been the great problem of Latin America for the last five centuries, because it’s prevented Latin America from growing their own food. It’s fought against the indigenous population feeding itself to turn the land into export crops, largely under World Bank guidance for all of this. 

Same thing in Africa. They say, wait a minute, what is happening in Israel is what happened to us, with the colonizing powers. This is what Germany did in Africa. It’s what the Dutch did in South Africa. It’s Germany in Namibia, the Dutch in South Africa, the English through Africa, and especially the French in its territories. All of this has occurred before. 

And all of a sudden, just as Americans go to the movies and mourn more for the Westerns, they’re cheering for the Indians against the cavalry. You’re having the rest of the world cheering for the underdog because the underdog is who they were. The underdog is them today. 

And this idea is turning into a feeling of, Let’s throw off all of the barriers to colonialism. 

Let’s start with French Africa, which we’re throwing off the French there. We’re not going to let French banks, French mineral companies, mining companies, French oil companies simply take all of our wealth because they conquered it five centuries ago. We can identify with the—we know what the Palestinians are fighting for. 

And yet, in a way, they’re also saying, well, wait a minute, look at what Israel’s doing. 

Israel says, God gave us this land. We used to have it. Well, the South Americans and Africans and Asians are saying, Well, this is our land, but we never left it. We’re still on the land. And even though we’re on the land, we’re still locked up, like Israel is treating the Palestinians. We don’t have to live this way. We can decolonize. 

And the whole split of the world and the turning towards the China, Russia, Iran, BRICS access is an attempt to reverse, undo, and roll back the whole colonial expansion that’s occurred over the last five centuries. 

HAIPHONG:You just gave an incredible summary in breaking down the interconnections of these developments, and I wanted to, given that the Near East, West Asia, is so “hot” right now. 

Iran just launched numerous strikes in Erbil, in Iraq, against a Mossad headquarters, as well as other targets locating certain terrorist groups that Israel supported. There are reports now of Pakistan, also in northern Pakistan. 

There also is the situation with regard to Yemen, the Red Sea crisis that is ongoing. The Ansar Allah movement has just hit an American ship. There’s constant activity there. And of course, there’s still the conflict you mentioned, the fighting going on in Gaza, the brutal attack on the people of Palestine that has been correctly labeled a genocide. 

And here’s what Joseph Nye had to say, and I’ll kick it back to you, Michael. He said it with regard to U.S. soft power. In that Financial Times article, he said, The U.S., even so, can seem powerless. It has failed to convince its ally, Israel, to act with restraint in Gaza. Could it have done so in the past? It’s not clear they could have done it 20 years ago. George W. Bush intimated in 1991 that American aid could be cut and that they may have helped to stimulate the Oslo process, but that didn’t bring about two states. Israel is not only, not the only ally that has proved quite capable of resisting the U.S., pointing to Saudi Arabia and others. For the moment, Israel is hurting its own soft power and by extension hurting American soft power. 

Kick it back to you, Michael. 

HUDSON:This is the big lie that America is trying to promote. The idea that, the pretense that when Blinken goes to talk to Netanyahu, he says, when you drop the next bombs and kill the next 20,000 Gaza-era Palestinians, please be gentle with them. Please obey the laws of war and stop bombing the ambulances, stop bombing the hospitals. 

That’s all public relations crap. The reality is that he’s telling Netanyahu to go forward. 

It’s America. All these bombs that are dropping are made in America and sent to Israel to drop. Every week, America is saying, Here is a new delivery of bombs. Go to it. Here is billions of dollars more for you to get by while you’ve drafted your working population into the army. America is pushing Israel. 

Beginning 50 years ago, I used to travel to work with Netanyahu’s main Mossad and now National Security Advisor, Uzi Arad. I remember, I think I’ve mentioned before on one occasion, we were going to Japan and stopped off in San Francisco for some discussions. 

An army officer came up, threw his arms around Uzi and said, you Israelis are our landed aircraft carrier in the Near East. Well, that was 50 years ago. 

Last week in the New York Times, I hear exactly the same phrase. Israel is our aircraft carrier. To the United States, Israel is America’s Ukraine in the Near East. It’s the United States that is pushing Israel to goad first Lebanon and then Iran into doing something that will justify a huge American attack, trying to do to Iran what Hillary Clinton did to Libya, utterly destroying it and destroying the population. In the process, grabbing its gold supply, we don’t know what’s happened to that, installing ISIS as its foreign legion in as much of Libya as possible and grabbing the Libyan oil supply. 

In the New York Times, in the Wall Street Journal and on TV, whenever they talk about Hamas or Hezbollah, they don’t say Hamas and Hezbollah. They say “Iran-backed Hamas”, 

“Iran-backed Hezbollah”. They don’t talk about the Yemeni army, the Houthis. They say the

“Iranian-backed Houthis”. There is a huge public relations push to convince the American population that Iran is the big enemy and President Biden says again and again that Iran is the enemy. The army, Petraeus, and the neocons have said from the very beginning, Iraq and Syria are merely the dress rehearsal for where we really want to go, Iran. 

Their hatred of Iran stems from the fact that they overthrew the Iranian government of Mosaddegh back in the 1950s, along with British help as usual. And they’re sure that, well, we’ve hurt you so much that we’re sure you must hate us. And since we know you hate us because of what we’ve done to you, we’ve got to attack you because we’ve made you an enemy by overthrowing your government when we grabbed your oil and put in the Shah that ran a murderous torture regime for a few decades in Iran. Well, that basically is the American policy that is goading it into a war that probably will be more disastrous for the United States than the war in Ukraine was. 

At least in Ukraine, all the Americans lost were Ukrainians. And I guess they had a few mercenary troops that they hired over there. But in the Near East, they’re going to lose a lot more than it was at stake in just Ukraine. They’ll probably lose Israel’s role as a landed aircraft carrier. And in fact, they’re going to lose a lot of their own floating aircraft carriers that are near there. And they’ve already lost control of the Red Sea and the oil gulf, basically, between Iran and Egypt. 

And there’s also a possibility that they’ll even lose the support of Egypt and Saudi Arabia. 

Because even though in the Arab Spring, the Americans pulled a “color revolution”, Arab Spring, where they replaced the hated Egyptian President Mubarak with his own protege, Sisi, who is now running it. Sisi is totally in the US pockets. And yet, the Egyptian population, needless to say, being largely Arabic, is supporting Gaza, not the United States. 

Similarly, in Saudi Arabia. Here, Saudi Arabia and Ukraine were in the process of making a rapprochement, actually an alliance with Israel, along sort of the same lines that Greece had been making with Israel for a Mediterranean military force. Well, now much of the Saudi population is Palestinian. They’ve found jobs in Saudi Arabia, and they’re outraged at Saudi Arabia’s trying to sit on the fence at the same time that it has joined the BRICS. 

It realizes that all of its foreign reserves are held hostage by the United States. What’s going to be more important to Saudi Arabia? Fighting to protect the Islamic population under attack, or saving its own reserves that are kept in the United States, not to help Saudi Arabia at all. 

Same thing with Egypt. 

The population there, between Egypt and Saudi Arabia and Bahrain, these were the main American bastions in the Near East. And now it’s in danger of losing them if, in the case of war, they’re under tremendous political pressure and instability. 

And further to the West in Africa, you have the former French colonies also being Islamic. 

You can imagine, you know, they’re breaking away not only from France and supporting the rest of Africa, Central Africa, from breaking away from France, but essentially moving into an alliance with the BRICS countries, with Russia and China. 

So all of a sudden, the American decision to go to war with Russia in Ukraine after the 2015 Maidan massacre and regime change, putting in the neo-Nazis, you’re having the fighting in Israel. And those two US-sponsored attacks have had the exact opposite effect of what the United States politicians promised. Just as they promised that Russia would break up and essentially the economy would crash under the sanctions and under the force of war, they believed that Israel’s army was so strong that it was going to simply be able to wipe out Hamas. 

And the big fighting—there’s not a word of this in the United States press—but the big fighting is on the West Bank. Netanyahu is saying, well, here while they’re all looking at what we’re bombing the civilians and the hospitals and the ambulances and starving Gaza, we’ve distracted the world and we can now wipe out the Arabs on the West Bank and move right into Syria on the Golan Heights. And apparently the United States has promised Israel that it can take whatever it wants of Syria, which it’s still opposing. 

We don’t know what Russia is going to do in all of this. Russia, China have been completely silent in all of this. And I can understand they’re silent. China has moved naval ships into the area because it’s itself is very dependent on the Red Sea and the sea lanes to oil in Saudi Arabia. 

When the United States keeps saying, threatening, oh, the Yemenis are going to bomb ships there and block the trade, that’s what they want. The United States realizes that if they can goad Yemen and Iran into blocking the Straits of Hormuz and the Gulf, this will indeed stop the oil trade. And it’s true that as Yves Smith pointed out in Naked Capitalism today, the sea lanes to Saudi Arabia were closed for many years after the 1967 war. They were closed numerous times for many months. And it’s not unthinkable that they’re closed. But that was then. 

Now, if you close them, it will be the main energy buyers in Asia, China, and other countries that are going to be hurt. And that is, from the United States point of view, that will give the United States even more power to control the oil supply of the world as a bargaining chip in trying to renegotiate this new international order. 

So you’re having the United States basically play the only tactic that it can actually use. 

It can’t use the tactic to say, We’re the growing economy and you want to trade with us, not with China and Russia, because they’re growing faster than the U.S. and Europe. They don’t really have anything to offer except the ability to disrupt foreign trade and foreign monetary and financial systems and agree to stop disrupting it if other countries will simply let the United States be the unipolar decision maker. 

And I should have added the dimension before when we were talking about China and Russia and the Siberian development. The Eurasian countries have one great advantage over the United States and Europe. The United States and Europe have essentially privatized what was the whole public infrastructure system. And being privatized, they’re now natural monopolies. And they’re run in the way that, say, Thames Water is run in England. They’re run as monopolies that are under-investing and simply using a choke-hold to increase their monopoly rents, which they report as profits. 

But China, Russia, Asian countries have kept the basic infrastructure—transportation, education, health care, communications—as public utilities. And they are investing, they are run by engineers, industrial engineers, not financial engineers. And they are run not only much more efficiently, but they don’t have the financial overhead and the monopoly rent overhead that plagues privatized infrastructure. So the cost of production in the non-neoliberalized world, I guess we can call it the world moving towards socialism, is so much more efficient than the neoliberal financialized West that you can see the magnetic pull of Africa and South America. 

And as it happens, these are also the main raw material suppliers of the world. So if the United States and Europe don’t have raw materials, don’t produce their own oil, except what the Europeans have to pay enormous markups to American producers, you’re going to have Europe looking pretty much like post-Soviet Latvia and Estonia. The population is going to emigrate. They’re going to shrink. You’re going to have a flowering of interaction throughout all of Eurasia and Africa. 

And essentially, the United States can try to stop this by triggering a new oil war in the Near East. But that’s really the last gasp. It’s very unlikely that this is going to lead Taiwan to say, Well, you know, we’re going to follow Ukraine and Israel and you can fight to the last Taiwanese, just as you’re fighting to the last Ukrainian, the last Israeli. I think that the United States is creating a turmoil that is demonstrating to the other world the need for essentially, I won’t call it an iron curtain, but for it to go its own way and for a break in economic systems. 

And as President Putin has said again and again, this is a civilizational war. It’s a war to say in what direction is civilization going to go? Is it going to be towards neo-feudalism, back toward feudalism, which is the neoliberal rent-seeking 1%? Or is it going to be towards where industrial capitalism was originally evolving towards, towards socialism and towards raising living standards instead of imposing IMF financial austerity on the dollar block? So that’s the choice that America is seeing in the Near East and in other countries right now. 

Are you going to have a future of austerity or essentially prosperity and economic growth? 

HAIPHONG:I don’t think there’s a better way to connect all of those developments, especially with regard to what’s happening in the Near East, or what some call the Middle East, or what others call West Asia. I mean, the clashes are escalating. There’s clashes even between Egypt and Israel, which is almost unheard of. 

With everything that you said, you’re saying that this is not going to work at all, that the United States won’t be able to wrestle control as it is seeking in the region. How do you see this playing out? Maybe we can close on this point, given that it’s not going to work. 

And if it’s not going to work, then what other options do the United States and maybe the broader collective West have? Because you’ve outlined it perfectly, this is an economic war, this is a war for economic dominance and control. So will it just crumble on its own, or will the United States and whoever it can drag along with it, you know, escalate and maneuver in a manner that we should all be aware of? 

HUDSON:The United States has one dynamic more than any other country of the world, and that is rage. That is the feeling that you have in Washington now. Not only rage, but as with most rage, it’s combined with fear. The Democrats fear that they’re going to lose the election and that Donald Trump is going to come in and clean up the FBI police state and to get rid of the CIA. That’s basically what he’s pledged to do, the deep state. 

So the deep state is worried that it’s going to be, not that the United States is going to be left to stagnate, but that they themselves, their control of the United States will stagnate. 

And the deep state is willing to destroy the U.S. economy. The Democratic Party, since Clinton, has the objective of destroying the U.S. economy in order to benefit the control of the 1% over the 99%. And it’s willing to use military war to fight, to escalate in the Near East, to escalate in Ukraine, and to escalate, presumably, in the China Sea to somehow provoke and essentially saying, Well, we’re going to go to war. We’re going to have a grab bag because who wants to live in a world that we don’t control? 

Well, just, you know, this is like what Russia said when America was threatening to atom bomb it with its withdrawal from the arms agreements. Russia said, Don’t think that we won’t fight back. Who wants to live in a world without Russia? Well, the United States government is saying, who wants to live in America that we can’t control? That the banks and the military industrial complex and the pharmaceutical complex and basically the finance-monopolist sector can’t control. If we can’t control it, we’re willing to have the whole country go under. That’s really what it is. And they’re using the control of the press for any of this. 

For instance, on Saturday and Sunday in Washington, there were huge demonstrations against the attacks on the Palestinians. Not a word of this in the New York Times or not a word of it on television. There’s not a word of what’s happening in the Near East or what President Putin and President Xi are saying in the news at all. It’s as if the world is already divided into a visible world, the deep state world and the invisible world, reality, of the 95% or 85%. 

The fight politically towards November is, are people going to be able to really believe that the Biden administration is helping the economy instead of defending the CIA, the FBI, the national security state, the military industrial complex, the pharmaceutical complex, real estate, and Wall Street against the population by de-industrializing? Or has all this been a detour that’s made us poor? That’s going to be the question. 

And the fact that you’re already having on social media, blocking of any criticism of Israel or the United States, you’re having a kind of control here that is a very similar control that you’re having in the Ukraine. 

HAIPHONG:It really is mind blowing how quickly all of these developments have, in many senses, spiraled out of control. Even if we can look at this in years, but even in just the last few months, of course, with October 7th being another breaking point. 

HUDSON:I think you should say October 2nd. That was the destruction of the attempt to destroy the mosque. It’s October 2nd that triggered all of this. It was the Israeli attack on the mosque that was intended to say, We are going to destroy the Islamic presence in Palestine so that it can be entirely non-Islamic. That was the declaration of war. So don’t be suckered into the New York Times saying it’s all October 7th. 

It began the week earlier, just as in Ukraine. The Ukraine war did not begin with Russia moving to protect its population, its Russian speaking population in Donetsk and Luhansk. 

It began not only with Maidan, but with the Ukrainian army shelling, bombing civilian apartment buildings and civilians in the Russian speaking territories and refusing to pay any social security or healthcare to the Russian speaking territories and banning the Russian language. Russia was the country under attack, not the attacker. 

So again, you have to be very careful as when you date the beginning of this. And the Americans want to date all wars as when after it attacks and when other countries are protecting themselves. They call other countries protecting themselves an attack on the United States. Yeah. 

HAIPHONG: October 7th, February 22nd, 2022. I mean, it’s a tactic. So it’s a great point that you brought up. 

And maybe, Michael, we could close our conversation with China because China, you mentioned earlier in your analysis. And, you know, I believe China is the end game here. And there are a few developments. You mentioned China surpassing, in terms of car exports, car manufacturing, Japan, and becoming number one in the world. There and I’m going to pull up the articles as you speak. 

There’s also the boards of the major auto manufacturers, the monopolies in a state of shock over BYD, the car manufacturer in China that has essentially taken over the world market with regard to electric vehicles. And there’s also reports that China is going to meet its 5 percent growth target. Despite the fact I’m sure you’ve seen this, Michael, there is collapse after collapse after collapse theory being bandied about in the mainstream media by the deep state. “China’s on the collapse. China’s economy is flailing. It’s declining. It’s crashing.” 

So, Michael, I’m going to pull up the pieces as you go. But perhaps you can give your take, your reaction to this development and the notion of China being the end game for the neocons and the monopoly system of post-industrial capitalism, finance capitalism that you write and analyze so much about. 

HUDSON:Well, there are a number of reasons why China is becoming the main car producer. This is led by the shift towards electric vehicles. And there’s one key dimension of electric vehicles. 

Number one is they’re electric. You need electricity. How are you going to produce the electricity: with American oil, with Russian oil? How are you going to make it with atomic power? The other thing is once you get the electricity into the car, how are you going to get a battery to run the car and not have to keep stopping at the filling station even more often than you have to go to the bathroom? 

Well, the answer is you need lithium for that. And China has been controlling most of the lithium sites. And you also need to have computerized vehicles. You need all sorts of materials that are cobalt, the rare earths that also are controlled with China. And China has gained control of most of the metallurgy, of the refining of the key metals that are needed for automobile production and for other industrial production. 

So you have China as an integrated economy producing all of these. And you have the West becoming dependent on achieving these same metals. Now, let’s look at what could have happened back in 1990. Suppose there had not been a Cold War. Suppose that America actually in 1990, when the Soviet Union disbanded, America would have disbanded NAT and really had a mutual kind of growth with open, continued international trade. 

Well, without the world splitting into the two parts, somehow there wouldn’t have been enough motivation for other countries to explicitly make the civilizational break from neoliberalism to socialism. There would have been a kind of social democracy in Asia, but it could have been the social democracy going the oligarchic way that it’s gone in, say, Sweden, which used to be called a great social democracy. And now it’s the most unequal country in Europe. You could have had slowly that development, but there would have been world trade and anybody could have bought the various metals, lithium, the rare earths. There would have been oil. There would have been continued trade and the whole world economy could have grown. 

All of that was broken up by the American insistence that if we can’t control world trade, there won’t be world trade. If we can’t control world international finance and make the whole world use the U.S. dollar that we can print on computers and print and issue to finance all of the military spending to encircle the rest of the world with military bases, if we can’t do that, then there won’t be a world financial system because the United States believed that without the dollar, there couldn’t be de-dollarization because there was no alternative. 

They’re tricked into the Margaret Thatcher type slogan. There is no alternative. And they really believe that the rest of the world could not prosper without using the dollar. They could not prosper without selling off and privatizing their public utilities and making natural monopolies that would be bought up by American buyers printing the dollars to say, we’ll print the dollars and we’ll buy your transportation system, your communication system and your factories. They couldn’t believe that there was an alternative to neoliberalism. And yet you’re seeing this. They couldn’t believe that if they simply bombed another country, that somehow the population of that country would say, Oh, we don’t want to be bombed. 

We’re going to overthrow our government and support a government that supports you so that you won’t bomb our country anymore. 

Instead, the effect of bombing a country when the United States does it is the same as bombing a country when any other country does it. It galvanizes the population together to oppose the country that’s bombing it and defend the country that’s under attack. So the whole image that the United States has is, there’s only one actor in the world, and that’s us. And we can smash other countries. And if that doesn’t work, we’ll upset the chessboard and just wreck the whole game. 

So the United States is acting in the role of wrecker and other countries are in the role of builder. And the whole global majority is saying, What side do you want to be on, the wreckers or the builders? 

And you can look at Ukraine as an example of how the United States would like Russia, China, and the Arab countries to exist. You would suspend elections once you have your guys, your president in there. You would become the most corrupt country in your region, as Ukraine has been. You will ban local languages and religions that are not Judeo-Christian. 

You will essentially prevent strikes. 

And you know the joke, the aristocrats. A stage group of actors talks about a family coming on and doing all sorts of horrendously devious sexual acts and incest, and it goes on and on. The producer who’s being offered this act and said, what do you call this act? And the answer is, the aristocrats. 

Well, what do you call the Ukrainian act of suspending elections, banning foreign languages, assassinating critics? We call it democracy. Well, that’s hilarious. That’s indeed what America calls it. America has two models of democracy, Ukraine and Israel. Again and again in the press, it says Ukraine is the model of democracy that we want for what used to be the whole Soviet Union. And you have Latvia and Estonia and Lithuania clapping, and we want the democracy in Israel. Israel is the only democratic country in the Near East. 

We want Israel to be the model for the Near East. 

Well, what are they saying? That there won’t be any more Arabs in the Near East? That they’ll all be Americans with dual citizenship? This is what it’s all come to. We’re living in an Orwellian world is trying to deter people’s consciousness from realizing the reality of work and the dynamics that are at work. And how long can you convince people that they’re really not doing well just because the 1% is doing well? How can you convince the people that America is really a model leader when it’s trying to destroy the whole rest of the world instead of helping it, as at least it could pose to be doing back in 1945 when World War II ended? 

You’re having really unwinding of the whole world system of the World Bank, the IMF, the United Nations, the whole diplomatic system of the world that was put together in 1945 is now being outmoded. And you could see the inability of the United Nations to cope with the war in the Near East, to cope with the war in Ukraine. This is the death knell of the old world. And you’re seeing a new world being created spontaneously, not ideologically, but basically spontaneously in an ad hoc fashion by China, Russia, and the 99%. 

HAIPHONG:Yes. Yeah, yes, indeed, Michael. And, you know, final thoughts on the fact that given all that you said, and this reality, I mean, it’s this myth and reality, the myth, the idea, that China’s collapsing, you know, China’s economy is in decline. And yet you have not only these recent developments, but you also have these broader developments that you speak of. 

So can you just give a sense, you’ve been to China, you’ve studied China’s economy very deeply. Just to close, help our audience here understand why China’s economy is able to industrialize like it is. 

Europe is about to go through this probe. I don’t know if you’ve heard of this, this probe of the, you know, Chinese auto manufacturing, especially around electric vehicles, because of these nefarious state subsidies. Can you talk about this, talk about China’s economy, how it works, and why Europe and the United States, of course, has been waging economic war as well, why they would resort to what seems to be counterproductive measures? 

HUDSON:Well, the key to understanding the West’s neoliberalism is privatization of basic needs and basic utilities. The most important public utility throughout history has always been the ability to create money and credit. 

And what China has that no other country had was its central bank created the own money. 

And when the government creates money through the treasury, spending money into the economy, it spends money in order to actually build things, mainly to build real estate, to house the Chinese, but also to build the high speed railroads, to provide an educational system, universities all over China, to build communications. 

Other countries, such as the United States, don’t have this. Money is created, especially in the United States, by commercial banks, and they create money not to finance new construction of factories or new investment of any sorts. Banks lend money in the West against collateral that is already in place. You can go to a bank to get money to buy a building that exists, an office building, although the office building’s prices are all collapsing now. You can go and borrow money to buy a whole company. That’s what private capital does. It buys money to buy Sears. It drives it bankrupt, collapses it, and fires the [workers]. 

It can buy Toys R Us, drives it bankrupt, collapses it, and it’s gone. You can buy companies and loot them and essentially close them down and turn factories into gentrified buildings for the 1% of financial operatives who are doing the looting. 

But banks in the West do not fund public utilities, and once you cut the taxes and force a government into deficit, you then finance the deficit by privatizing your roads, turning them into toll roads. You privatize your postal system. You privatize your health care system so that there’s not much health care anymore, as you have in England, for instance, the crisis that you’re having in English medicine and hospitals and privatization. You make the whole economy in the West look like England after Margaret Thatcher, where people who are actually wage earners can’t afford to live in London anymore. That’s for the foreign investors or the people who work in the financial sector. The wage earners have to live in suburbs to take privatized rail transportation. 

In the United States, for instance, Greyhound, the bus system, was just bought out by private equity. They did exactly what Stagecoach, England’s largest bus company, did in England. They sold off the bus terminal that was in the center of the city that people would go to to catch the buses, and they sold it for gentrified real estate and told people, there’s now a parking lot we have on the outside of the city. You go and wait in the parking lot. 

We hope it’s not raining or too cold or snowing, but we don’t have a terminal anymore. Well, you can just imagine this way of doing things. It turns into a race to the bottom. 

Well, China, by [keeping control of] finance, really controls who is going to get the credit, and credit is really the economic planner. Neoliberalism in the West says the government shouldn’t do the planning. Wall Street should do the planning because Wall Street is what provides the credit that determines who is going to get the resources and what they’re going to do with it. 

Well, Wall Street gives the credit to financial engineers that are trying to make money by increasing stock prices, increasing capital gains, and making money financially. 

It’s true that China has made many billionaires. That was part of the Let 100 Flowers Grow, but now that it’s had that spontaneous growth, now it’s seen what forms work and what forms don’t work. Now it’s consolidating the economy to essentially create credit to finance tangible industrial growth, tangible infrastructure growth, tangible agricultural modernization, and general improvement of living standards. 

The whole aim of the Chinese economy is growth, not looting and downsizing and a smash-up of corporate raiding. There’s no corporate raiding going on in China. There’s not going to be any financial interest that’s going to buy Huawei or the other Chinese developers. You don’t have the parasitical financial class that have become the central economic planners of the United States. 

Because that’s what libertarianism is. Libertarians want a centralized economy, not run by government but run by Wall Street and the financial sector. The libertarians are essentially the advocates of what normally used to be called fascism, central planning by the wealthy financial and monopoly sector against the population at large. 

You have the Republican and the Democratic Party both supporting a dismantling of government just with a different kind of rhetoric, but the same policies, the same military policies and the same anti-industrial policies. China, Russia and their now more and more BRICS countries are rejecting that whole self-defeating neo-feudal path of growth. 

HAIPHONG:Well, Michael, you’ve been very generous with your time today. I really appreciate you giving this what was an incredible rundown of all the interconnections, all the developments geopolitically that have, at their base, economic roots. And so, Michael, thank you so much. 

Where can people find you? I have your website in the video description. 

HUDSON:My website is michael-hudson.com and there’s a Patreon list associated with that. But all my articles are on my website and the other sites that I publish on, Naked Capitalism and Counterpunch and other such sites. 

HAIPHONG:Well, definitely check out his work. He has a number of books that are key reads. So, Michael, it was great to be with you. Thanks so much for joining me today and I’ll talk to you again soon. 

HUDSON:Thanks for having me. We were lucky politically, but the whole world was at a turning point this week, it looks like. 

Photo by Jigar Panchal on Unsplash

The post Credit the Economic Planner first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Perfecting Imperialism

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 18/01/2024 - 11:17pm in

Tags 

Interviews

Michael Hudson: “US imperialism, Krugman, de-dollarization, socialism, Palestine, China.” India and Global Left, January 13, 2024, with Jyotishman Mudiar. “This is the problem China will face.”

JM:
Hello, and welcome to another episode of India and Global Left. Today, we have with us the economist Michael Hudson. Michael, welcome back to India and Global Left.
MH:
Good to be here.
JM:
Last time you came here, the show went very well. We have got almost 100,000 views and a lot of people liked that, and we discussed super imperialism, among other things. One of the things that we discussed was the role of the World Bank, especially with regards to developing countries, and how it recklessly pushed its agenda of capital accumulation that ultimately hampered the struggle for land rights, struggle for collective ownership of concentrated wealth.

One of the statements that you made was “the World Bank has always been an arm of the US military.” A lot of people reacted to that by saying that Michael has got everything right, but the US military is indeed an arm of the World Bank, not the other way around So I thought I would have your response to that, because it ties so well to one of your arguments in super imperialism that US imperialism has a lot to do with the state instead of private corporations. Your response?

MH:

Well, you can use google to look at the background of the people who’ve led the World Bank. From the very beginning, John McCloy was in the army. The most notorious World Bank leader and most corrupt was Robert McNamara, of course. And then you have the last few World Bank presidents who come directly from the US national security state. So, if you look at their background, you may ask, why is it that they come from the military or the national security state?

Well, the reason is that they look at the World Bank as a key to the US strategic control of other countries’ economies. And there are two basic spheres economically that the United States uses as the buttress of its balance of payments and its ability to impose sanctions on other countries. The first is oil, which explains why the United States has blown up the Nord Stream pipelines and why it’s isolated Venezuela. It used oil to be able to control the energy of foreign countries. And the second point is agriculture. And that is probably the most serious and most negative, destructive element of all of the World Bank’s policies. And I have a chapter on that in my Super Imperialism.

The function of the World Bank is to prevent other countries from growing their own food, to make sure that the World Bank does not give economic support to domestic agriculture. One of the most fateful requirements of the World Bank is that it only makes foreign exchange loans. Now, foreign exchange loans mean they’re going to develop the export sector, they’re going to develop roads and transportation for export commodities. The government will bear the cost of developing mining, of developing oil and minerals, of deforestation, but it won’t develop domestic industry. And if you look at agricultural development in the United States, most of this agricultural development spending is domestic.

There’s farm extension, there’s education, there’s price supports domestically to support domestic grain, there’s a whole plan of creating a family-based agriculture. And if you look at the World Bank reports of the 1950s and 1960s, you’ll find every country report, the ones that are published by Johns Hopkins, the advisors to the World Bank says you have to have domestic currency to support domestic agriculture and food sufficiency. Not a single loan has been made for that unless it’s for plantation agriculture and export crops. So, the idea is that other countries, Latin America, Africa, South Asia, should depend on American farmers for grain and food exports and they should export plantation products that do not compete with American agriculture because products that are equatorial, that depend on domestic weather and domestic soils.

While the World Bank is supporting these export crops, it basically serves as a market for American corporations, the big infrastructure corporations. And it also supports the private investors, US mining affiliates, US oil companies, US forestry companies. The idea is that countries will increase their exports to be able to pay for these loans, but the mining companies, instead of having to build their own roads, instead of having to build their own infrastructure, the World Bank convinces governments to pay for these to essentially support the private sector and then support the private sector avoidance of paying taxes.

The World Bank has opposed land reform. It’s opposed any of the domestic rules that any country such as the United States, or the European Common Agricultural Policy, have used to support domestic food production. So, what the World Bank has done is subsidize import dependency on American grain. And the export competition with other World Bank customers to compete among themselves at products that do not compete with American or Western Europe production. So, the World Bank is basically an arm of economic warfare by the United States and NATO against the global majority.

JM:
A lot of countries in the global south actually has long faced the problem of balance of payment crisis, and then it becomes a big tool to control economic policies and restructure economy in a way by these global institutions. And that is primarily because the global south has been exporting low value commodities, and the global north essentially exports a lot of high value products, to begin with industrial commodities, but now also services and so on. So, there is always this very desperate need of foreign loans, and you give these foreign loans and then they redirect a lot of economic policies.

MH:
The important thing to know is that there was an alternative to the World Bank. It was called the World Bank for Economic Acceleration, and it was promoted by the American senator from Florida, Senator Smathers, and was called the Forgash Plan after Morris Forgash, who was the head of the containerized shipping. The World Bank for Economic Acceleration was to finance land reform, it was to finance domestic subsidy for agriculture and domestic import displacement, and of course that was opposed by the United States.

I found out that it was opposed because a copy of the plan was sent to my former boss at Chase Manhattan Bank, John Deaver. Deaver said, advised David Rockefeller, that every country that is engaged in land reform has ended up a political enemy of the United States. Well, that’s because the United States subsidizes assassination squads to kill any advocacy of land reform, so that the United States can control the land of the country’s most notoriously United Fruit Company. To the extent that the World Bank has supported agriculture, it’s supported foreign-owned plantations, not domestic economies.

The idea of the World Bank is to turn Latin American, African, and other economies into extensions of the US economy, not serving their own domestic economy. When you look at the World Bank, it’s creating an America in Brazil, America in Argentina, working hand in hand with the International Monetary Fund to put the financial squeeze on countries that don’t comply with this pro-American trade strategy, then you realize that you need an alternative set of international institutions whose goal will be to promote domestic development and domestic independence in food independence, basic consumer goods independence, energy independence, instead of dependency on the United States.

JM:
I think this is a good segue into one of the questions that I had for this discussion, which is on de-dollarization. You have been at least suggesting hopes regarding de-dollarization, and I wanted to bring to viewers’ attention that Paul Krugman in the New York Times wrote an article called De-Dollarization Debunked. What he argues basically is that de-dollarization is very unlikely, following up on Charles Kindleberger’s Idea, that a stable global hegemonic currency is important for global financial stability. He argues that most of the international market is in dollar because of its private trade, financial transactions in the private account, and banks recording these transactions in dollar, and he says that the reserve currencies that different countries hold are actually very tiny minuscule of the overall transactions in dollar. And the final point that he makes is that the alternative, which is the Chinese yuan, is not possible because China still maintains capital control and nobody would like to make yuan its international currency because that would not be a free-flowing currency. What’s your thoughts on that and why do you think that de-dollarization is not just important but also possible?

MH:
Well, there are two things that Paul Krugman has shown that he does not understand in any article he’s ever written. First of all, he does not understand money. All of his economic models assumes that money doesn’t exist. They’re barter theories. That’s why all of his trade discussions are called the barter terms of trade. The other thing that Paul Krugman does not understand is balance of payments. Now, the reason that he is so popularized is because he does not understand them. If he understood the balance of payments and money, he wouldn’t be popularized. He’d be here with me talking to you instead of writing in the New York Times.

De-dollarization doesn’t mean having an alternative currency like the euro or the dollar or the yen. It doesn’t mean a domestic currency at all. De-dollarization means how do you avoid having to keep your reserves in dollars where the United States can simply confiscate them as it confiscated, along with Europe, $300 billion of Europe’s money. It’s now threatening to grab all of Saudi Arabia’s American holdings if Saudi Arabia opposes the joint American-Israeli attempt to take over the Near East and attack Iran.

The proposals to replace the dollar don’t mean using each other’s currency. You’ll denominate trade in each other’s currency. You’ll have, of course, some holdings of other countries’ currencies, just as every country holds other countries’ currencies to stabilize the foreign exchange market.

But the big problem is what do you do to keep your international reserves, the savings of the country, in a kind of global money? In other words, what do you do to replace the role that gold had prior to 1971? The problem is that the growth in international reserves itself is a function of American military spending. Almost all these dollars that have been ended up in the bank accounts of foreign governments have been injected into the world economy, not by foreign trade, not even by foreign investment, but by foreign military spending. Again, I showed the statistics in Super Imperialism and in the monographs that I’ve written. The US private sector for many decades was exactly in balance. It was the government sector and specifically the military sector that pushes dollars into the foreign economies. And what are foreign countries going to do with the dollars, especially countries like Japan or China, which were the big accumulators of dollars in the 80s and 90s?

Well, the United States will not let these countries do what the United States does to them. It won’t let these countries buy major American industries. It won’t let them buy control of any major technology. It will only let these dollars be invested in US Treasury securities, or maybe in the stock market, or maybe you can buy scattered real estate. But if it’s in the stock market, it can’t be control of American companies like corporate takeovers. It can only be very minority holdings. Well, this doesn’t give other countries much safety in their reserves. The problem is the fact that these reserves are unnecessary in the first place. The reserves measure imbalance in international trade, investment, and payments. And if the world worked the way it’s supposed to in the economic textbooks, countries would be imbalanced. You would export goods and that would pay for your imports. You would invest in foreign countries. That would enable you to earn the money to plow back into new investment in foreign countries or to depend on them.

So, none of this appears anywhere in what Paul Krugman has ever written. His discussion of international trade theory on which he made his reputation doesn’t talk about the balance of payments or reserves or even money. I know classmates of his who went to MIT with him he told one of his classmates, you know, the professor said don’t talk about money, it’s too controversial. So, he’s the last person that you would ever want to talk about either money or international reserves. He does have an economic degree but he’s employed as a democratic party hack. And if you read his editorials in the New York Times, they’re propaganda basically for the Biden administration. And that’s his job. His job is to defend American policy and basically foreign policy as well as domestic policy by distracting attention away from what is really important in international currency and that is why are reserves going up? Where do all these dollars come from?

If you didn’t have American military spending, if you didn’t have the American looting of global south countries, you wouldn’t have this growth in reserves. And the fact is you wouldn’t need them. You would need basically some international credit so that when a country running a balance of payments surplus, let’s say China, would invest in a belt and road initiative it would essentially have a claim on other countries. It would hold a claim on them but it wouldn’t use it as a means of saying well we owe your own your currency and we’re going to throw this currency onto the market and force you to devalue unless you follow our policies and impose economic austerity on your labor force. So basically, the World Bank and Krugman supports the international monetary fund’s approach to international currency saying in order to hold the dollar you have to stabilize your currency in terms of the dollar by pushing down the value of your labor. You have to oppose labor unionization. You have to charge high rates of interest to be paid to the American banks or the European banks. You have to impose austerity so you will not have labor developing your own industry to compete with the United States.

The lack of international reserves is used to prevent countries from expanding the economy to support the employment and investment and government infrastructure spending that has made the United States and the West rich. Well, the global sub-countries and the global majority want to get rich in the same way that the United States has done and that China has done by public infrastructure investment. This entails some sort of international agreement as to how to handle transactions between foreign investors and domestic countries.

You remember under President Obama the trans-pacific partnership idea. Other countries are not allowed to fine American or any other oil companies for pollution or mining companies for pollution. They can’t charge any damages for violation of the environment. They will bear all of the environmental costs of oil spills, of mineral pollution, of all the others. If they try to tax these countries or fine them, they have to pay an enormous fine that will leave them basically bankrupt internationally. The fact is that access to international credit, to international reserves, is used as a kind of political leverage to force them to follow laws that will not tax American and European firms, that will let them use accounting stratagems to pretend not to earn any profits at all at home, but to take them in offshore tax havens and offshore banking centers to pretend that there are no profits.

The whole international financial system is a massive pretense to avoid paying taxes to the countries that are the host countries for investment and to avoid making companies responsible for the economic damages that they cause to the environment and to the rest of the economy. All of this is part and parcel of the international reserves and the international financial system. That’s what Krugman and the United States, national security people, and basically trade strategists want to prevent. They want to keep the system the way it is. They don’t want other countries to be able to avoid dependency on the United States and the IMF and the World Bank for what they can and cannot invest in. If you’re looking at reserves, you want to put it in the whole context of where is the overall economy going and where is the all-regional economy for the 75% of the world that doesn’t want to be governed by the United States and NATO is going?

JM:
This is very helpful because you have placed it in the right context that de-dollarization is not about all these transactions that are happening, but it is essentially about the reserves for different countries that is created by some imbalance of flows between different nations and how the centrality of dollar in that reserve is then used by the American central bank and the American government to blackmail through economic policies. Paul Krugman notes that, yes, reserves maintained in dollar are falling from perhaps 72% to some 57%. Then he brushed aside saying, well, that’s not important. Look at how the transactions are going, which are basically the barter that you are referring to.

MH:
I want to say one more thing about the reserve. Why did the United States go off gold in 1971? It’s because General de Gaulle in France and Germany were doing the same thing, were cashing in all of the dollars that were thrown off by American military spending, mainly in Southeast Asia but around the world in the 800 military bases. If you had the gold reserve or a reserve controlled by the global majority, then the United States could not simply finance its military spending by printing dollars. The idea of de-dollarization is to prevent the United States from printing dollars on its computers in order to buy your industry, simply by printing dollars to build military bases and to spend on attacking you, simply by printing dollars without any constraint at all.

When General de Gaulle and Germany and other countries were cashing in their dollar’s week after week in the 1960s, the group that I was associated with, the Columbia group, Terrence McCarthy, Seymour Melman, and myself, were saying this is what is going to constrain the United States from further fighting in Vietnam and Southeast Asia. When you say keep the dollars, you’re saying keep the American ability to spend an infinite amount of dollars on military spending and on buying control of your economy, simply by printing dollars instead of earning it through exports.

Despite the fact that the United States is deindustrialized, despite the fact that it cannot produce its own what it needs for trade, its own products, despite the fact that it’s basically become the world’s largest debtor, it continues to print all the dollars without constraint. De-dollarization doesn’t simply mean giving an alternative to the global majority, it means to prevent the United States from parasitism of host economies, and that’s what the United States is. The dollar glut is a parasite on the host, the host being the appropriately named host countries that hold these dollars.

JM:

We had Professor Jayati. Ghosh and we discussed the problem of sovereign debt crisis, and she said that one of the ravages of giving the U.S. Central Bank its global power through monetary policy is that every time there is a hike in the interest rate, money, short-term money, flows out of the global south and comes back to safety, leaving the countries devastated, and then IMF, the World Bank, they go in and redirect economic policies towards neoliberalism. This perhaps is a good segue into neoliberalism itself.

I mean, a lot of focus of this show goes into understanding capitalism, and as we stand now, perhaps we are in some life cycle of neoliberalism, even some people are arguing that we are beyond neoliberalism, and we have been focusing on the labor side a lot. We had Professor Richard Wolf in the show and he discussed a lot about how the U.S. labor movement was smashed and so on. I want to discuss with you the side in the capital markets that happened with this neoliberal transformation or neoliberal revolution, anti-revolution, whatever one likes to say. Breakdown for us, what were the changes that happened in the capital markets and how did it destroy industrial capitalism and how did it transform capitalism all over the world?

MH:
You’re quite right to recognize that the focus of neoliberalism is the capital market. Neoliberalism is essentially the doctrine of finance capitalism as opposed to industrial capitalism. Industrial capitalism wanted to lower the cost of living and the cost of doing business by having the government invest in basic infrastructure to provide basic needs, education, healthcare, transportation, communications at a low cost so that the employers did not have to pay their labor high wages. They could afford to have a low cost of production to compete with other industrial countries.

Neoliberalism seeks to maximize the cost of production by financing it very largely by debt financing. Debt financing is basically used to make short-term gains. The financial perspective and time frame is a short-term time frame as opposed to industrial capital where you have to invest in long-term factories and employing labor, long-term development of market. Finance capitalism makes money financially and you can make more money financially by deindustrializing, by buying a factory, firing the workers, closing it down and renting out the factory as luxury housing, and gentrifying it. New York used to be a manufacturing center a hundred years ago and even fifty years ago. I’ve lived in New York, many manufacturing buildings. Near Wall Street there was a dairy and butter and nut importing and electronics area. All that has been gentrified into very high-priced housing.

Neoliberalism makes money by buying and selling assets, not by producing goods and services but by essentially financializing the real estate and the value of corporations by credit. A house or a corporation is worth whatever a bank is going to lend to the buyers of that house or to the corporate raider of a corporation. The corporate raiders will take a public infrastructure private. You’ve seen this in global South countries, again being organized by the World Bank from about 1950 to let’s say in the 1990s.

For at least 40 years the World Bank made loans to governments to build roads, dams, electric utility companies, everything that the American investors needed as their infrastructure. But now having built all this the World Bank says, well that’s what we’ve made in the old way, but now the neoliberal way is we’re going to take all of these companies that we’ve lent money to the governments to buy and we’re going to privatize them.

In fact, the IMF is going to tell them, well if you owe the money that you’ve borrowed from the World Bank and from American investors in the false belief that we were trying to help you and the money that you borrowed, it hasn’t worked out the way we promised you that it would. You’re still in deficit and your currency is going to go way down, and your cost of living and imports are going to go way up if you don’t begin balancing your international payments by selling off the roads that we’ve built. Turn them into coal roads, take the water and sewer systems that we bought, privatize them, sell them to investors, and use that money that you get from selling off your communications infrastructure, your transportation infrastructure, your other infrastructure. You’ll use that money to repay the foreign creditors for all the loans that the IMF and the World Bank told you were going to make you rich instead of further and further in debt.

So, neoliberalism is sort of, after being badly advised by imperialist investment and trade theory policies promoted by people like Krugman, they now have to pay for following American advice by losing all of the investment and selling it off to foreign investors. So, there’s no more government control, government ability to subsidize these roads and communications. And of course, when the private investors take over, they’ll do what the water companies have done in England and other countries do.

They raise the prices of hitherto public services, so that these prices now include not only profits, not only high management fees, but also a very high debt service because companies avoid having to pay any income tax on the infrastructure that they’ve bought out by making them a loan to their balance sheet, using the loan to repay the parent company or another arm of the parent company, one of their affiliates. And so all of the profits are absorbed in largely fictitious debt service, so that the countries that sell this infrastructure don’t even get taxes from the enormous monopoly rents that are being ripped off by the purchasers of these privatized infrastructure companies. So basically, neoliberalism is financialization, privatization, untaxation, and a lot of political assassination, a lot of killing of people who oppose this.

As the head of the CIA said, we’re murder ink and who do they murder? They murder people who are trying to explain and expose this whole imperialistic process, and that’s what American embassies are for, to choreograph this political interference with other countries, with promoting right-wing oligarchies, especially military oligarchies, that will impose pro-IMF, pro-World Bank, pro-NATO, pro-US investment policies, tax policies, neoliberal policies, and overall economic control.

JM:
I’m glad you said neoliberalism is about finance capitalism, and this is perhaps what makes this discussion very important, especially for people in the left, because we generally, at least some of us, generally wants to remain stuck at the labor theory of value. The problem is, when the classical economists tried to theorize capital, capital markets itself were much less important.

In fact, if you read Braudel’s writing about the 17th and the 16th century, he says that capital was not even the most important factors of production. In fact, he meticulously records merchants and Chamber of Commerce’s papers, where he says that there is a lot of capital, but it doesn’t know where to go, because increasingly there were the Malthusian pressures on food, on fiber, on energy, and so on, so capital was not the most important factors of production. With neoliberalism, capital markets have become the most important and most powerful force to restructure economy.

MH:
Well, part of the problem is just what you said. The left is concerned mainly with the labor theory of value. Value is the cost of production. The problem today is economic rent. Rent is the excess of market price over value. What has been missing from the left today is what was central to the entire political economy of the 19th century, the classical economics that Marx perfected in volumes two and volume three of Capital.

Marx pointed out that the labor theory of value explains the exploitation of labor by its employers, but he also said that’s only part of the economy. What about most of the labor theory of value from Ricardo and Adam Smith on was to isolate the economic rent of landlords. Labor produces value, but how is it that landlord’s control so much of the European economy? It wasn’t by producing value. It wasn’t their labor, and they didn’t employ labor to make a rent.

Land rent was simply a hereditary privilege of the warlord Norman invaders and the warlords who took over feudal Europe in the 11th and 12th centuries. Land rent was what gave and essentially endowed the whole European landed aristocracy. The same thing for finance for banks. Banks do not create value. When you go into a bank and want to borrow money, the bank will simply say, all right, we’ll plug it into the computer. You’ll sign this IOU for a hundred-thousand-dollar house and we’ll give you a hundred thousand dollars in your bank account on which you will have to pay interest. Interest is not part of the labor theory of value. The labor theory of value was to say what portion of national income is not necessary, is not spent on labor, is production. What portion has nothing to do with labor or production or industrial capital or even industrial products?

It turns out that most of the income and most of the wealth made today is not made by creating value, which is employing labor. It’s by buying a monopoly privilege, by buying real estate, by running a bank or by using debt leverage to extract the interest or to have the central bank inflate the bond market, inflate the capital market and the stock market as it’s been doing under the monetary ease of the post-Obama depression from 2008 on. All of this wealth has nothing to do with creating value.

It has nothing to do with employing labor. In fact, all of this increase in wealth by the financial class, by the real estate class, by the insurance class and what I call the FIRE sector- finance, insurance and real estate- has been created in the form of economic rent. Not wages, not profits, but land rent, monopoly rent and financial returns. And by the increase in the monetary and financialized debt finance, increase in the price of housing, the price of stocks, the price of bonds, the price of buying a financial income, which has been very highly concentrated in the hands of the wealthiest 10% in the United States and Western Europe.

JM:
You mentioned about the FIRE sector. I mean, this morning’s Financial Times comes up with a report on the problems that the major U.S. banks are facing and it essentially records two major problems. One is the rising interest rates and the other is the non-performing assets. It records that the four major banks, you know, Citigroup, JPMorgan Chase, Wells Fargo and so on, its non-performing assets have gone up recently and it is recorded at $24.2 billion. And if you read the report, one of the nervousness that is expressed is the property sector. It says that the banks are essentially finding it difficult to to profit through its mortgage loans and it is really become a cause of concern.

MH:
Well, what you’re pointing to is to the self-defeating characteristic of neoliberalism and finance capitalism. If you try to make money financially instead of by industrial, instead of industrially, then the industry is going to close down and move to China and Asia. What’s going to happen to all of the factories and the real estate that these factories were in? And if you’re going to aim at moving your employment out of the United States into low wage countries as part of your class war against labor, then these offices are going to close down and the factories will close down. And who’s going to pay the rent on all of these buildings?

Well, commercial real estate that owns these buildings is very different from homeowners’ real estate. A homeowner has to, at least traditionally, you have to make a down payment 10%. In my day, it was 30% of the purchase price to buy a home. But commercial buyers, people like Donald Trump, they won’t put down a penny.

They’ll say, well, I want to buy this 100% of the money and I’m going to buy this building. And then I’m just going to wait for you to inflate the economy and charge, I’ll just charge rent that I make in my sleep. And I don’t create value just making in my sleep, economic rent and all these rents, and the increasing value of the property that you’re from your inflation, I’m going to pay you the rent from the income that I get. And I’m willing not to keep the rent for myself. That’s why the real estate sector doesn’t pay income tax largely. I’m going to basically I’m after the capital gain of the rise in property prices is the rent, the rental yield goes up.

Well, how can the rental yield go up if you’re deindustrializing the economy, if you have the Federal Reserve saying, our job at the Federal Reserve is to create unemployment, it’s to lower the price of labor. And you’ve had the last two heads of the Federal Reserve say again and again, whenever wages go up, this threatens American profits. So, we’re going to raise the interest to create austerity, to create a downturn so that labor will not have its wages and living standards increased. So, bank management, financial central bank management is anti-labor.

But if you’re anti-labor, then you’re against employment. Again and again, the head of the Federal Reserve has said we want to increase unemployment, Marx called that the reserve army of the unemployed, so that it’ll be harder for labor to get jobs and they’ll have to fight against each other to compete and lower the wage rates or at least keep wages from going up. So, whenever the Federal Reserve reports wages going up or employment going up, the stock market plunges. When employment goes down, the stock market booms because they say that’s good for profit.

Well, if you’re going to be anti-employment, the offices are going to close down because there’s nowhere to go to work. You’d think that was obvious enough, but the newspapers and the Fed says the building is not performing, it’s a non-performing loan, the landlord is not having enough money to pay the interest. So, what you’re having is that landlords are simply not paying the mortgage and they’re going to be like all of the homeowners that found in 2008 that they had to pay more money for a mortgage than they could go and rent an apartment, an equal house somewhere else. You’re having the commercial building owners walk away from their property and there’s an idea that maybe 20 percent of property is going to be just abandoned. Well, what’s going to happen?

There will be some market for turning these office buildings into luxury apartments. Luxury means really unpleasant schlock. It’s sort of like the kind of apartment that Donald Trump builds. His buildings are known for being schlock, very poor design, bad walls. I know the architects and they say, oh my god, what he’s made us do, that’s just junk. Well, imagine if you say, I’m going to live in what used to be a big bank building on Wall Street or Broad Street.

Well, it turns out that if you can imagine how these buildings are, they’re going to be a lot of bedrooms without windows. Well, the problem is that the New York real estate laws say that every bedroom has to have a window for ventilation or just for light. So, there’s a question, can these office buildings, bank buildings, financial buildings, other office buildings, can they really be turned into residential, gentrified apartments?

Nobody knows what’s going to happen. Are they going to be torn down? What’s going to happen? So, the banks are left with assets on the book that they’ve lent, let’s say, a hundred million dollars for a given building that’s supposed to be yielding, say, five million dollars in interest every year, and all of a sudden, they’re not getting any interest from it. And the value of this loan has gone down to who knows what. Well, what do you do? The banks will say, let’s give this mortgage to the Federal Reserve as a deposit and the Federal Reserve will give us real money for it. Let the Federal Reserve and the government take the big loss. That’s the only hope of getting out of this because 80% of bank loans are mortgage loans.

And the problem for the last 10 years, people have said, the result of the Obama depression and the fight against labor and the Democratic Party’s fight to lower wages is going to be a property collapse. Well, that’s exactly what you’re getting, a commercial property collapse that everybody’s foreseen. All of the smart buyers have already gotten out and they’ve tried to sell these office buildings to pension funds and naive investors, basically, or maybe to German banks. The Germans believe that Americans would never cheat them. So, that’s basically where the action is these days.

JM:
In fact, these days they are specifically mentioning office buildings and commercial property sector. They’re not even mentioning saying real estate, that’s perhaps too old now. It’s very specific, office building and commercial property sector.

One of the things I want to ask you is what basically caused the Federal Reserve to raise the interest rates? Because there is a lot of nervousness about rising interest rates. Banks are failing. A lot of that has to do with the fact that its asset goes into bonds and a lot of stocks. And every time you raise interest rates, their bonds don’t rally, or collapse. And it erodes the assets of the banks and so on. And the ideologues of neoliberalism, including the Financial Times, has always lobbied for lower interest rates. So, despite all that, what led the Federal Reserve to raise the interest rate?

MH:
Well, the head of the Federal Reserve has given speeches week after week after week explaining that very question. He says, we’re raising interest rates because we see wages going up. We’re raising interest rates in order to cause unemployment to lower wages. We’re raising interest rates for the same reason that Paul Volcker did in 1979. Paul Volcker carried in his wallet a list of the wage rates in the construction industry. He said, when the wages in construction go up, I’m going to raise interest rates to discourage construction so that it’ll be more expensive to take out a mortgage loan and you’ll have unemployed construction labor. And he said, most construction labor, that’s what the immigrants work for.

That’s what raw manual labor is. And if we can lower the living wage for immigrants, especially for racial minorities, especially for blacks and Hispanics, it’ll spread to white people. And white people won’t be able to get many jobs either. And raising interest rates will just create enough unemployment so you’ll have labor competing with each other and wages will go down.

And the same speech, almost word for word, has been given by the Federal Reserve presidents and say, we’re going to raise interest rates until labor suffers, until we make it scream. And when it screams, then we’re going to know that this is going to help increase profits and maybe that will help re-industrialize the United States by impoverishing labor. This is exactly the opposite of how the United States got industrialized in the late 19th century by offering high enough wages for labor to have a good education, to be well fed, well clothed, well housed, and to be more productive.

If you’re going to impoverish labor, you cannot expect this labor to be more productive. You’ll have a labor pretty miserable at its job and they’re not trying to be more productive. If anything, they’re doing what Thorstein Veblen described as industrial sabotage. They’ll just try to fight back as much as they can. To put it briefly, the class war is back in business and it’s being led by the Federal Reserve.

JM:
I like how you link Marx’s reserve army of labor with Fed’s interest rate policy. I mean, it’s incredible. Talking about industries, I mean, you have been for so long talking about the destruction of industrial capitalism, especially in the Global north. And there has been talks about re-industrialization of the Global North.

I mean, the Financial Times and the New York Times went all over during the times of the Inflation Reduction Act, saying that it’s somehow bringing in new industries through sub-government subsidies and so on in the green technologies. Emmanuel Macron wrote a piece in the Financial Times and we had a brief conversation through email on that where he said that I am very hopeful of making France the hub of green technology, artificial intelligence, semiconductor. These are things essentially the Global South are perhaps too dumb to produce.

I mean, he doesn’t say in these words, but this is what he meant. There is a lot of talks about increasing tariffs against Chinese electric vehicles and so on, all in the hope or at least the narrative is -Europe and the US are going to re-industrialize itself. How do you look at it?

MH:

Well, when Macron and the US talk about industrialization, what they mean is just what you pointed out, creating an information technology monopoly. How can they create some monopoly to get monopoly rent? Industrialization that NATO countries are talking about is not about employing labor. If you’re going to make money, as you say, by making computer chips, this is not going to employ manual labor. It’s not going to raise wages.

In fact, the Biden administration gave tens of millions of dollars to build in, I think it was Arizona, a big plant to make computer chips that were going to be run by a Taiwanese company. The Taiwanese company said, well, the problem is there’s no American labor to work there. We’ll have to move our own labor in because you’re not training people to make computer chips. You’re not training people in industry. Your schools are all assuming that we’re in a post-industrial economy, so why train people to go to work in industry? If your idea of industry is to build a technology monopoly, whether it’s in pharmaceuticals or information technology, you’re not really employing labor. You’re employing very high-priced specialists with a highly educated PhD level, computer training, IT training, pharmaceutical training, microbiology. This is not the kind of labor that Marx is talking about for the industrial labor. Industrialization really is about making things like you have in your house, making your furniture, your kitchen utensils, making the house itself.

This is not the kind of industrialization that America and Europe are talking about. The problem is that if you’re talking about manufacturing type of industrialization, we know that Europe is a dead zone now because in order to make manufacturing you need energy. It uses fire, it uses energy to run the machinery. America has said you can’t trade without Russia for that. America has also said you really can’t trade with China either. So, the Europeans have complained to China and said it’s really not fair.

We’re buying more from you than you’re buying from us. And China said why don’t you sell us this computer chip etching machinery that the Dutch make? That’s national security, we can’t sell that to you. We can’t sell you anything that you need. Isn’t there something you don’t need that we can sell you for buying what we do need? Your metals, your special minerals, all the other things that you make.

And China says well here’s the problem, when we export, you’re absolutely right. It’s not right for us to export more for you than we’re buying because we’re going to end up with euros and the euro that’s going to go down because you’re a dead zone now. You’re wrecked. America has wrecked you. Why do we want that? And we don’t want dollars because America deindustrialized.

What does America produce that the rest of the world wants except saying we have something that you do want for us not to atom bomb you, for not to do to you what we did to Libya and what we’re doing to Gaza and what we’re doing to Syria and what we’re doing to Ukraine? That’s what we have to offer you. Well, that speeds the parting guest. So, it’s not really an economic model, it’s a militarized what used to be called imperialism.

JM:
One of the main reasons of the recent German slowdown of its economy is the high energy prices. In fact, today’s Financial Times carried a long coverage about the difficulty of recruiting people in its oil and petroleum sector, which is making these oil barons, the shale oil barons, Chevron, BP, they are pouring in money in American universities in a way to recruit because they feel that people are moving away to this green technology and artificial intelligence.

The interesting thing is both are, I mean, the green technology chips and so on are so high tech, which as you said, doesn’t require manual labor and cannot employ large sectors of the population. And no wonder why in the US there is no renewed push for public education, because if you want to employ most of your population, then you have to make them educated. But essentially you can think of reindustrialization without educating your people only because you are talking about a very intellectual property right driven industrial sector, if at all that’s an industrial sector.

I want to ask you a little bit about China, because it’s so difficult to understand China because of a lot of propaganda on one hand, and on the other hand, it’s really a mixed picture. On one hand, they have retained public ownerships of their major means of production, including the banks. The party does act as a supervisor against big businesses. And then on the other hand, there are troubles, like very substantial destructions of industrial labor relation that has basically left Chinese labor to the hands of the employers, mostly private employers, because a lot of the private sector, I mean, non-major sector is in the private hands now. The real estate sector has been very cheaply privatized or rented out, which has led to enormous levels of inequality. I mean, one has to cringe to see new levels of inequality in China being close to South Asia, which is perhaps, along as Latin America is the most unequal in the world. So give us a sense of how to understand the Chinese economic system.

MH:
China tried to avoid the problems of Stalinism, and during the late 1970s, around 1979, 1980, they thought, well, we want to do something like Lenin’s New Economic Policy, let a hundred flowers bloom. And they didn’t want any Marxists to come over from the West, because most Marxists, they assumed, were basically the old Communist Party Stalinist Marxists, and so they invited Milton Friedman over. Friedman had quite a few followers in Shanghai, and he convinced them, and obviously rightly so, he convinced them to open up the economy and say, you know, there’s no way you can plan for what’s going to be an innovation, something people want. Let the imaginative entrepreneurs develop the economy and let’s see where it goes.

Once they develop it, then you can figure out what’s the right tax policy, what’s the right regulatory policy, but you want to just see where it goes. Let China do entrepreneurs do their thing. Let everybody try to get rich and see who’s getting rich in a way that benefits the economy in the most positive way, and then we’re going to choose to encourage the beneficial ways of getting rich, and we’re going to discourage the non-beneficial way of getting rich.
Well, that’s what they’ve been doing. You could say that’s the basic issue of every country, but it’s especially the issue in China, and that’s exactly what’s going to shape Chinese politics and the economy over the next 10 years. How are they going to decide to tax away on making rents and financial gains, but permit profits on industrial gains?

They want to promote industrial capitalism, not finance capitalism and rentier capitalism. Right now, what they’re dealing with is that we’ve let our real estate get very highly debt-leveraged instead of taxing economic rent. We’ve let developers pay it to the banks to fund into yet more development, and it’s gone off the charts. We can’t do that anymore. They’re looking for an alternative way of avoiding the kind of real estate bubble that has characterized the West.

Now the issue of China is not how do you make Mao’s communist economy more like the West to get the West’s good points. Now it’s okay, we’ve done that, how do we get rid of the West’s bad points? You could say that that’s the choice confronting Chinese policymakers today.

JM:
I want to ask you about rethinking socialism in the 21st century, and it’s a difficult question for multiple regions. For instance, the Soviet Union acts as a model, but it’s a very flawed model. On one hand, it was highly successful in rapidly industrializing itself, free healthcare, tackling problems of unemployment, making housing available, and you can go on and on. On the other hand, there were severe problems. One of the problems was dysfunctionality with market, international trades, dynamism in its economy after the war, and so on and so forth. What do you think could be some of the ways for the left in terms of at least have a vision of socialism for the 21st century?

MH:
I think the question you’re asking is exactly the question that economists asked throughout the 19th century. It would help to study classical economics and realize how the whole question you’ve asked was framed in terms of value and price theory and rent theory. You want to increase wages and profits. You don’t want economic rent. You don’t want land rent, monopoly rent, or financial rent.

That was the whole issue that was discussed and that was what Marx wrote about in his theories of surplus value. He reviewed all of these and explained how to put the economic system together. You don’t just look at labor and employer relations. You look at the whole economy and how people get wealthy. The left does not look at how people get wealthy. I don’t see much concern at all with that. Wall Street is concerned with that, the right wing, not the left.

The left is concerned with how labor is getting poor. That’s very interesting. How are poor people being exploited and how are ethnic minorities being exploited? That’s very interesting, but I’m more interested in how does an economy get rich and how do they get wealthy in a good way as opposed to the bad way. The left says, oh, wealth is bad. I’m exaggerating. The left doesn’t care about the economy. The left cares about the victims. It doesn’t look at who’s doing the victimizing. How does the victimizing process work? That’s not in their agenda.

They’re looking at how do we describe the victims in the most heart-rending way and make money doing it, basically. In all the years that I was working, writing about imperialism and how finance capitalism was destructive, my intellectual market was the financial sector, the right wing, brokerage companies, wealthy people.

The left had no interest at all because they said, oh, you’re not interested in the minorities and the poor people. I wanted to say, what is it that’s making the poor people? I’m not interested in once they’re poor, how you wring your hands. I’m interested in what is creating all of this inequality in this economic polarization. I’m interested in the overall economy.

The left could say, well, we’re not interested in the economy. We’re interested in political science or whatever it is. The hope for the left is really what is happening outside of the United States and Western Europe because part of the American imperialism has been to promote a false left. When I’ve been criticizing the left, this isn’t the left of my generation that was concerned with what I’m talking about. This is the non-governmental organization left supported. This is the World Economic Foundation left. This is the Ford Foundation left. This is the bleeding-heart liberal left financed by the finance capitalists that the last thing they want them to do is to talk about how the economy is about finance capital at the top much more than the victims at the bottom.

JM:
Last time you came here you said how why the banks and the financial companies in the 1960s would recruit a lot of leftists and Marxists because they knew how capital works and today perhaps they would recruit people from the left who can talk merely about diversity, equity and inclusion.

MH:
Well, they don’t have economic research departments anymore so the banks today are not like they were in the 1960s. If they were, somebody who was interested in the imperialism like I was could go to work for a bank to learn how imperialism worked. That was where I learned it. I did not learn it from the universities about how it worked. I didn’t learn it from reading the old left that I came from out of.

I learned it by actually working for the banks on Wall Street because they wanted to say how can we make exploitation better, how can we perfect imperialism and that was their concern and that was my concern of explaining how imperialism works. So the banks now say we don’t have to understand the economy, it’s all an insider deal. All we have to do is finance who’s elected as president in congress and do an insider deal. We don’t need to know what we’re doing. You don’t need to be smart to make money. You don’t need to understand how the world works. All you need is greed and corruption.

JM:
I want to leave you with this one final question since you have been writing so much about imperialism in general and we are seeing the ongoing destruction and genocide in Gaza. The New York Times today comes up with this reporting saying we have to be very happy now because the IDF has said that Israel has switched to some sort of calibrated attack and finding ways which is less destructive in the south in Gaza. I wanted to ask you your thoughts about US complicity in this destruction.

MH:
Well, if you believe what you read in the New York Times you’ve lost all credibility. The United States is there to tell Israel how to hit the Arabs harder. Blinken is there today, the Foreign Secretary Blinken, to say here is how you’re going to attack Iran, here is how you’re going to attack Syria. But we know that you’re very unpopular in the world and now that South Africa has brought the claims against you, you’re making us unpopular too because we’re your backers.

We’re going to keep giving you the bombs and when we give you the anti-personnel bombs, please be gentle with them. When you kill more than 10,000 people at a time, do it gently. Because most Americans now, today in New York, the whole news at noon, four demonstrations against the attacks on Gaza.

So, the United States says, well, we want our warmonger Biden to be re-elected, so we have to pretend that we’re not supporting you. We want to pretend that we’re saying, oh, please be gentler. Well, here are the new bombs, here’s how you’re going to kill, you’re going to attack Iran, here’s how you’re going to attack Lebanon in the next week or two. So all this crap about we’re going to be nice, the United States is urging other countries to be nice. This is just for domestic propaganda consumption. You’re not being nice when you send Mr. Blinken there saying, I’m with you, kill them all. And that’s what Blinken is saying, that’s what Biden is saying. And of course, ultimately, there will be a fight back from Hezbollah. And you can just hear Blinken and Biden cackling together saying, we fought to the last Ukrainian, now we’re going to fight to the last Israeli. And we’ll end up holding the Near East once we fight to the last Syrian and the last Iranian. That’s basically the United States policy.

The New York Times is just the propaganda agent of the American attack on the Near East. It’s really the United States that’s behind it all, that’s pushing it. It’s the United States that gives Israel the armaments, the United States that is funding Israel. The United States is doing to Israel exactly what it has done to Ukraine. That’s what you should bear in mind. The United States is not telling Mr. Zelensky to be, please stop bombing the civilian buildings in the Donbas and Luhansk region.

Kill the civilians as many as you can, that may lead to a regime change. Do the terrorism by attacking Russia as much as you can, we’ll use that domestically to try to get an anti-Putin movement going. That’s basically how to interpret what’s happening. The United States is not pushing peace anywhere in the world. That is why the Republican alternative to Donald Trump is Nikki Haley, who says let’s change the name of the Defense Department to the War Department. I think she’s got the pulse of the military industrial complex that is backing her candidacy quite clear and explicit.

JM:
Michael Hudson, thank you so much.

MH:
Well, thank you.

Photo by NEOM on Unsplash

The post Perfecting Imperialism first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Debt Makes the World Go Around

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Sun, 14/01/2024 - 9:05am in

Tags 

Debt, Interviews

RADHIKA DESAI: Hello and welcome to the 21st geopolitical economy hour, the show that examines the fast-changing political and geopolitical economy of our time. Welcome also to a new year that promises to be nothing but rocky, so let’s help rock it in the right direction. I’m Radhika Desai.

MICHAEL HUDSON: And I’m Michael Hudson.

RADHIKA DESAI: There’s an old saying, money makes the world go around. Like so many other truths, neoliberalism has subtly but decisively altered this one too. The adage of the neoliberal age can be said to be “debt makes the world go around”. Indeed, debt is not just making the world go around, it is making it spin madly. So madly that the possibility that it will spin out of control is ever present. Everywhere you look, there’s a debt crisis. There’s a student debt crisis, the mortgage crisis of 2008 never really went away, there’s the commercial real estate crisis, there’s a government debt crisis, and of course, there is the crisis of housing. I mean credit card debt, Auto debt, etc. To keep the debt cycle going, the Federal Reserve is even changing its decade-long tolerance of intolerance of inflation. For the Federal Reserve, inflation is acceptable at 3.5%. According to some reports. It would rather tolerate 3.5% inflation than sacrifice the asset markets that keep going up thanks to which have kept going up thanks to low interest rates, and it doesn’t want to take interest rates beyond a certain level. Raising interest rates at this point means making it harder for asset markets to go up and stay up, and that’s why the Federal Reserve is going to cut interest rates no matter whether it’s managed to solve the inflation problem or not.

So today, we are going to continue our closer look at more than four decades of neoliberal policy and how they’ve changed our economy by focusing on the triangle of debt, real estate, and financial instability. In short, we are going to talk about how in these decades while incomes have stagnated, debt has expanded such that households, governments, and businesses have all become indebted to the gills. Today, one of the reports shows that debt servicing itself has gone up by 50% and today accounts for almost a sixth of total government spending in the United States. How both residential and commercial real estate have become bound up in the vortex of financialization is another thing we want to talk about because it is not producers but rentiers who benefit from this type of economy, and even rent is being converted by the alchemy of financialization into interest. So at the end of the day, even land ownership and homeownership no longer matter. What matters is how much money you’ve got and how you can make your money, make more money.

So finally, we are going to talk about how even though all of this has benefited the financial sector, given its very nature, the expansion of the financial sector can only lead to crisis, and so how the mountain of debt today threatens the stability of the US financial sector and by turn of the US economy, and as Michael and I have discussed so many times, the dollar system itself. So let’s start looking at this chart. Michael, this is a chart, um, let me just find it, this is the chart of total indebtedness in the United States.

So you see here, this is simply the aggregate level of indebtedness. The kind of blue bits at the bottom are business debt, this green bit here is household debt, this purple bit here is federal debt, and then on top, you have state and local government debt which of course as people will know has been restricted by constitutional, by legal means. So what you have here is debt from the 1960s onwards, and you can see clearly that really the debt, the accumulation of debt begins to take off only out in the neoliberal era from the 1980s onwards, and it really begins to take off around the 2000s when of course the United States Federal Reserve first experimented with low-interest policies, and of course, which then resumed after the 2008 financial crisis.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, you can look at the basic sweep which is an up sweep, an exponential growth. Any debt is a doubling time, and there’s something very unique about this kind of slope. The economy doesn’t grow like that, the economy grows in business cycles, up and down. What you don’t see here is very much of a downswing, and that is because the growth of debt continues to mount up by compound interest. The creditors, the banks, simply reinvest all of the interest that they get in making new loans, which is exponential, and they can create their own money simply on their own computers.

So, this chart really should be juxtaposed with one of the business cycles, then you’ll see that any debt that grows this rapidly exceeds the ability to be paid, and that is the distinguishing feature of debt for the last 5,000 years. The natural tendency of debt is to exceed the ability to be paid.

Now, this chart simply shows debt by the sector that owns it, the household sector, business. What it does not indicate is what this debt is for. What is it collateralized for? Well, almost all of the household debt is for real estate, and the same thing with commercial bank debt. 80% of bank loans for this debt are real estate loans. And the blue chart of government debt really doesn’t matter that much because the government simply creates the debt. And it’s debt that doesn’t ever expect to be repaid. Households and businesses have to pay the debt. That’s what’s causing the problem. Nobody ever got into trouble running into debt. The government doesn’t run into trouble running into debt because it can simply print the money to pay. But individuals, families, and corporations have to pay. And when they can’t pay, that hurts the banks, and the banks go under. And the purpose of the Federal Reserve is to make sure that this debt keeps on growing despite the fact that it is stifling the economy and leading to depression.

The role of the central bank is to impose austerity on the whole rest of the economy to make us look like a third world country in paying the debt, because this is exactly the same kind of sweep that you have for the global south countries owing their foreign debt and for every country in the west. So the whole west, Europe, the United States, has a chart just exactly like this, and they’re all slowing down, and they’re all in what’s called a debt deflation right now.

RADHIKA DESAI: Well, you know, I’d just like to add a few more points because this chart is really kind of more interesting than might appear at first sight. Of course, there is the upsweep that you talk about, Michael, but there is also the fact that if you look at the period from essentially from about 1950 till the end of the 1970s, there is an upsweep, but it is not so pronounced. What you see now in the neoliberal era after 1980, and particularly after about 2000, that’s when you see the really exponential increase in debt. And I think that that, as I say, coincides with two very important things.

Number one, the repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act, which meant that this was essentially permission for the U.S. financial sector to simply enter into the most breakneck competition with one another in order to lend more and more, speculate more and more, and so on. So that’s what you’re looking at. And of course, the other part is the historic decision after the 2000 crash, the dot-com bubble crash, when the Federal Reserve first began experimenting with low interest rates. So you had sort of one, between one and two percent interest rates from about 2000 till about 2004-5, when because the dollar was coming under a lot of pressure, the Federal Reserve was forced to start raising interest rates. And that graduated series of interest rate increases was, of course, what eventually pricked the housing and credit bubble. So, I mean, that’s one thing.

The second thing as well is that United States government debt as well. You know, at one level you can say that, yeah, sure, the government debt doesn’t have to be paid off. But the thing is, it’s not as though the government debt does not matter. At the end of the day, even when the U.S. government, or when even the U.S. government borrows a lot, it does suffer. Because today, the U.S. government is having to pay much more money in return for its debt in order to borrow from the market than it used to have to. So, and even in the era of low interest rates, U.S. government paid a higher premium, higher interest rates on its debt than, say, a country like Germany, for example.

So in that sense, I think that what you see here, which is particularly after the increase in the debt in the neoliberal era, this initial increase here you see up to 2008, is basically created out of essentially giving tax cuts to rich people. So that expanded the federal deficit, even though you had cutbacks in Social Security and so on. And today, a very large part of U.S. debt is actually going to paying interest rates, paying interest on U.S. government debt. So in that sense, it’s important.

And then finally, of course, the expansion of household debt, which again, you see it increases, it increased a little bit in the 1980s, then it sort of slowed, but then you see it particularly increasing in the 2000s with the housing and credit bubble. Then it slows again, and then once again, it is increasing. And this increase, of course, is almost entirely because of the difficulties in which U.S. households find themselves. So on the one hand, at the top end of the borrowing, of course, you have borrowing in order to consume more, in order to spend more in one or the other way, including in order to speculate more in stock markets. But on the other hand, you also have a lot of distressed borrowing. So this is what we are looking at.

And finally, this increase in business debt is also because essentially what has been happening over the last several decades is that companies are bought by other companies. And then what these companies do is they burden every business they buy with as much debt as they can get in order to essentially use the money for other purposes, including giving fat dividends to owners and so on. But this is what you’re looking at. So we’re looking at a highly, highly indebted world.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, there are a number of points also in that chart. After 2000, a lot of that government debt was the war debt, the Iraq War debt. From 1950 through about 1980, almost all the growth in government debt was military spending abroad. And this debt is not only owed to the United States holders and the Federal Reserve, but the foreign government. So that is not included in the chart, but that’s much of the growth. The interesting thing also is that you see this acceleration of debt after 2008, and yet that was the period of zero interest rate policy.

When the Obama crash occurred, the Federal Reserve said, the one thing we have to make sure is that families bear the brunt of this enormous financial fraud and bad lending and junk mortgages that have taken place. We want to save the banks and we want to sacrifice homeowners for it. We want to make the public pay to the banks to make sure that homeowners lose their home and lose money. Businesses go bankrupt, but the banks continue to get richer and richer with this debt, and this debt will not get wiped out by bankruptcy. It’s going to grow and grow, just like student loan debt has grown. And you see a lot of this business debt going up, and yet this business debt was almost interest free, very low.

What the chart should be correlated with, if we really had a group of charts, was all of this debt was spent not on producing goods and services, not in building factories and means of production, not in employing labor, but in buying stocks and bonds and speculating. It was all used to buy companies, load them down with debt. And so this corporate debt that’s going up is a result of the mergers and acquisitions, the corporate raids, the corporate takeovers, and treating corporations in a way that would make money for their stockholders and their private owners, but not for the economy at large.

So a company would make money, suppose you take over Sears or Toys R Us, the private capital that would take over, they would borrow the money, hardly any interest from a bank, 100%, buy out Sears or another company. The first thing they’d do is say, okay, now we’ve taken over the company, could be the Chicago Tribune, let’s take the pension funds that’s invested in stocks and let’s borrow against that. Let’s let the pension funds lend the money to the company, and let’s borrow more money from the banks to the company. And the money that we borrow, we will then pay out a special dividend to ourselves. So the money goes from the banks to the owners without having any positive effect at all, but having a very negative effect. It leaves the company so deeply in debt that it goes bankrupt, like Sears or Toys R Us or all of the other companies that have been essentially going bankrupt. And when they go bankrupt, they’re sold to larger and larger companies. And so this debt has the effect of concentrating ownership within the sector.

And the household debt has gone up because as you increase the amount of money that banks will lend against housing, banks have competed. Who can lend the most money against homes for new families wanting to buy a home? Well, the banks compete to lend so much money that if you’re a family buying a home, you have to borrow more money than your rival who’s borrowing from their bank, and the banks have just created a new real estate bubble. And that’s what we’re in now. The real estate prices have gone up so high, the rental price is so high that one of the byproducts of this is a rise in homelessness. And with all of this debt, somehow people don’t have enough money to buy goods and services, and standards of living have gone down. We’re living in a increasing third world austerity plan as a result of this upsweep in debt.

RADHIKA DESAI: No, absolutely. And you know, what you say reminds me that we’ve already said that one of the reasons why especially poor households borrow is because they basically cannot make ends meet. They have to borrow, and so they are becoming indebted.

But there’s another reason, and that is, you know, why has there in the neoliberal decades been such a huge explosion in student debt? It’s because government cutbacks have stopped funding universities to the same extent. So fees go up. And of course, the cost of living goes up for students because of course you can’t rent anything half decent, or even indecent, unless you pay a lot of money. And so all of these things drive up the cost of an education, which then means that students have to get a loan, and so on.

So essentially, cutbacks in social services, including, by the way, we haven’t talked about medical debt. A lot of the debt is incurred because people have to borrow money if they want to pay for certain medical procedures. So all of these things just goes to show that once again, under neoliberalism, it’s ordinary people, the working people, and the poor people who get really shafted.

There’s another way in which these people get shafted. When you have a low interest rate fueled competition for buying houses, buying homes, typically the sharpest competition is happening at the lower end of the market. So that the lower end market, that is to say the kind of houses and homes that first time buyers will buy, tend to see the most appreciation in prices as a result of competition among the lower end buyers. And this is what prices out so many people.

But a final thing I want to say is this expansion of debt is also interesting because it has taken place exactly in that era when the government, right at the beginning of the 1980s, committed itself to restricting money supply, it committed the Federal Reserve to restricting money supply in order to slay the dragon of inflation. But what that has meant essentially is to have an economy in which people are making less money but incurring more debt. And essentially debt becomes the way in which money is issued into the economy.

And of course the Federal Reserve itself has kept up a policy going back to 1987 where no amount of money creation is too much if it is to bail out the financial sector. So from 1987 onwards, when you had the 1987 crash, Greenspan first engaged in this kind of liquidity provision in order to bail out the financial sector. It was called the Greenspan put. Now over the years it has become a Federal Reserve put. And the result is, you know, we just showed you the chart of indebtedness. And according to the Federal Reserve, the total debt or non-financial debt in the United States is now close to three times U.S. GDP. It has doubled since 1980.

There is another point that is really interesting. These charts, the chart we showed you, does not include the vast amount of debt which the Federal Reserve has itself created in order to bail out the financial sector. And the top end of the corporate sector, starting in 2020, on which the financial sector relies for its best assets.

So essentially, and this was very surprising to me, in 2008, a scholar called James Falkerson from your university, Michael, from UMKC, showed that the Federal Reserve could not cope with the 2008 crisis by just playing its normal role of lender of last resort, by providing ample liquidity, slashing interest rates, etc. It slashed interest rates at that time from 5% to 0%. But this did not function to stabilize the system and even made it worse. And then, according to Falkerson, the Federal Reserve engaged in a host of unconventional measures, unprecedented in terms of size or scope and of questionable legality. They’re his words. And the goal of these was to explicitly improve market conditions. And this program, according to him, amounted to a total of 29 trillion dollars.

MICHAEL HUDSON: You’ve gone very quickly over that, and I want to show how revolutionary this was. Until from the founding of the Federal Reserve to 2008, there was a basic philosophy of central banks going all the way back to the Bank of England and to the rules that people discussed in the 1880s and 1890s. The idea of central banks, you use the word lender of last resort. That means everybody realized that sometimes when there would be a business downturn or a shift in interest rates, people would have very sound property. The buildings weren’t destroyed when they became insolvent. Companies weren’t destroyed. But the problem is there was a temporary downturn in the business cycle. So banks are supposed to only borrow for short term and at a high penalty rate. Every central bank in the world followed the policy. You don’t subsidize rates for credit for banks.

Since 2008, the banks have taken control of the U.S. Treasury and taken control of the Federal Reserve to get all the money that they want for nothing. Actually, they’re paid to borrow. After 2008, the Fed said, we’ve got to make bankers richer. Despite the fact that they’re paying themselves more than any other sector, they don’t have enough money to keep on lending. We will give them all the money they want. The way we’ll do this is the banks will make loans to corporations for takeovers, make loans for commercial real estate. They will transfer these IOUs to the Federal Reserve in deposits. The Federal Reserve will lend them money in exchange for this. The banks have put all of their bad loans and shaky loans into the Federal Reserve. The Federal Reserve pays them interest on these deposits. The banks make interest not from the corporate borrowers, but the Federal Reserve is creating the interest to pay the banks to make this huge upsweep in loans. You can look at that as an arm of Chase Manhattan and Citibank. Essentially, they’ve taken control of the Federal Reserve.

That’s really the libertarian ideal of a centrally planned economy planned by the banks. When the libertarians say, let’s get the governments out of business, let’s get the governments [to not] run a deficit, that means if the government doesn’t run a deficit, it’ll cut taxes, it’ll cut spending. That means that all the credit that people need, the economy needs, will be produced by the banks.

The Fed has said, now we’re going to really turn up the screws. We’re going to let the banks make 5% of the money. All of a sudden, this growth in the blue, the government debt that you saw, is going to soar. The interest rates are going to be such a large proportion of the government spending that they’re already talking about, we’re going to have to cut back Social Security and Medicare. That’s what Haley, the Republican nominee, says. The Republicans want to say, if there’s a choice between paying Social Security and Medicare or paying interest to the banks and bondholders, the bondholders come first because they’re our campaign contributors. You don’t get campaign contributors from people who are broke because they don’t have the money that the banks have. Of course, we’re going to bail out our campaign contributors. The government itself has been privatized. That’s what neoliberalism is. That’s what the anti-government libertarianism is. It means liberty for the banks and debt system for the population at large. That’s what these charts imply.

RADHIKA DESAI: Absolutely. I would say just one thing. Of course, most people will know this, but in case people don’t, the Federal Reserve is peculiar among the central banks of the world in being still privately owned. In that sense, I think that what Michael says is very relevant. Essentially, what the Federal Reserve has done is over the last many decades, it has transformed the U.S. economy into an economy in which the primary way, the best way, the fastest way to make money is by essentially speculating, not by investing in the production of goods and services that ordinary people need, but by inflating the value of goods and services already produced.

Those of you who know a little bit of Marxism might appreciate it, but if Marx was around, he would have called it a very peculiar form of necromancy. What do I mean by that? Because already produced goods and services contain the dead labor that has gone, it is now dead, it is no longer living, that has gone into producing it and you are inflating the value of that. Whereas, as you do that, you are disvaluing the living labor, much of which may remain unemployed, and all of which is necessary to produce the new goods and services which every year, in every period, ordinary people need. We need more food, we need more clothing, we need more transportation, we need more housing, etc., etc. And these are the things that are strangulated. Living labor is strangulated while dead labor goes up. Because there’s something very peculiar.

Remember, as Michael pointed out, and as I pointed out, a lot of this debt has been incurred. In fact, most of it has been incurred to speculate, to inflate the value of already existing assets. And there’s something very peculiar about it, because imagine a house that goes up in price by 30%, 40%, 50%. Nothing in it may have changed, but it goes up in price anyway. Nothing is produced, but it goes up in price. So, this is the kind of economy that has been created.

And I just also want to show you one other outcome, just my last point this time around, but one other outcome of this vast increase, this vast federal government program to bail out the financial institutions. So, you see here, this is a chart of the total assets on the Federal Reserve balance sheet. And you see here, from up until the 2000s, it was basically hovering at about just below one trillion dollars. In the 2008 financial crisis, it doubled, a little more than doubled actually, to over two trillion dollars. Then over the course of the decade that followed, thanks to quantitative easing in which the federal government essentially started a program to buy the worthless assets of the financial institutions for good money. This was quantitative easing, and so it piled on, it increased its own balance sheet while essentially making good the damaged balance sheets of the very financial institutions that had caused the 2008 financial crisis. And then it was beginning to reduce its balance sheet when 2020 came, the pandemic came, and then you see that you have seen an absolutely unprecedented increase to $9 trillion of assets in the federal government. And this is the result of that $29 trillion worth of effort that the Federal Reserve made to bail out the financial sector.

So, please, Michael, go ahead. Yeah.

MICHAEL HUDSON: When you use the [phrase] “worthless assets”, they weren’t exactly worthless if you could get 100% from the Federal Reserve. The word that was used by Marx and almost everyone in the 19th century and today was “fictitious capital”. In other words, all of these debts and bank assets were counted as an asset. If a bank makes a loan to a large corporate property owner in an office building, the bank has that as an asset. But as we’re seeing today, these asset prices can’t be realized. In other words, what if the bank said, okay, now your mortgage is just falling due because it’s a balloon mortgage, you have to pay that. Every few years, you have to pay the entire amount or re-borrow it. Well, all of a sudden, if it’s lent $100 million against an office building, and the office building is now worth $40 million, why would a bank lend $100 million to an owner of a $40 million office building? That’s the situation we’re in today.

Now, look at these two jumps. The first jump that you have after 2008, that’s the junk mortgage jump. All of these loans were against fictitious mortgages, mortgages that pretended that there was value there, but there were mortgages mainly to Black and Hispanic borrowers by banks who cheated them, who over-evaluated the prices. The banks in general discovered a new way of making money after about 2004. They could make money by charging racial minorities much higher rates, almost double the rates that they charged white people. There were whole banks and brokers that specialized in this, and this was basically the junk mortgage group. Countrywide, Financial was the most obvious beneficiary of this.

There were a number of notorious banks that ended up being merged. Bank of America was one of the crooked banks. Citibank was one of the most crooked banks, as has been very well documented. Randal Wray at the Levy Institute and Kansas City published a big explanation of who were these $29 trillion, $27 trillion of loans for. It ended up many of these loans were rolled over and reloaned, so the net amount was not $27 trillion, but that’s how much was given to the banks with this huge jump. Instead of sending the bankers to jail, they made them billionaires. They rewarded them. That was the Obama policy, and that is what makes them one of the most viciously racist presidents in modern American history. The Democratic Party became committed to returning to its pre-Civil War racist policies.

Well, the next group is you see in 2020-21, this huge jump in bank loans. What were they from? The Federal Reserve began to raise interest rates. When the Federal Reserve raises interest rates from less than 1% to 5%, this means all of a sudden debtors had to pay 10 times as much interest as they did before. What that did was that reduces the price of an asset. It’s an inverse proportion to the interest rate. All of a sudden, the stocks and the bonds held by the banks that went under were fictitious. In fact, although Silicon Valley Bank and New York Bank went under, all of the banks, especially Citibank and Chase Manhattan, had all of the loans that they had. All of a sudden, they were not worth anywhere near what they carried them on the books. The banks were insolvent.

Now, here was a wonderful opportunity. The Federal Reserve could have taken them over by the government and said, you’re insolvent. We’re going to wipe out the stockholders and the bondholders because you’ve made bad loans. Instead, the Federal Reserve said, well, instead of making the banks insolvent, let’s make the economy insolvent. That’s the policy we’re in today. This increase in Federal Reserve loans has been to support this upsweep of credit that is increasing the burden. All of this upsweep in credit is far in advance of the wages and salaries that people are getting. Somehow, all this increase in interest charges and amortization charges and penalty fees end up impoverishing the economy by leaving less to spend on food and clothing and other consumer spending. If consumer spending is going up, it’s because of the inflation.

RADHIKA DESAI: A small correction. This big increase, of course, was increased because the Federal Reserve started a new, massive liquidity provision program, quantitative easing program, when the pandemic hit. And the one that you’re talking about, where essentially they were bailing out Silicon Valley Bank, etc., this is the small increase here, which is what happened after interest rates started rising. But throughout this period, right up until about here, interest rates remained at historic lows.

And just one other thing I wanted to say about this before we close this chat, which is that, you know, around 2013, about here, essentially, the Federal Reserve decided that it was going to try to decrease the size of its balance sheet. So you can see, you know, it was still only about three and a half trillion, not the nine trillion that it is today. But you know what the financial institutions and the financial sector did? The financial sector at the time, in 2013, threw a “taper tantrum”. The Federal Reserve was threatening to taper its balance sheets essentially, you know, to decrease it. And they said, we’re not having it. You’ve got to keep supporting us and you’ve got to buy our assets. And so essentially, the Federal Reserve humored them in their tantrum and they continued to expand the balance sheet. And then, as we saw in the pandemic, did even more so, etc. So that’s the thing we’re looking at.

And the other thing I just wanted to point out, of course, is that, you know, I completely agree with everything that Michael said about just how racist the system is, because at the end of the day, you know, people think that debt is a market relationship. Debt is not a market relationship. It’s a relationship between, on the whole, relatively privileged people, one of which decides to lend money to the other. So the idea that somehow, by passing a piece of legislation, you can make the poor people of the United States, the black people of the United States, the Hispanic people of the United States into homeowners, this was always a bit problematic.

And in the end, the whole 2008 financial crisis, the vast buildup of debt that preceded it, only a tiny fraction, which happened towards the very end of that vast increase, was actually loans to subprime borrowers. The financial institutions only began lending to the subprime borrowers once they had filled the prime borrowers to the gills with all the debt they could take, and only then they moved. And so, in many ways, the subprime borrowers came last, and they were also, of course, the ones to suffer the most. So, yeah, I mean, I think these are really, so really we are living in an economy that is awash with debt, as we were just saying, and it really is the opposite of the sort of economy we ought to have.

And Michael, you know, one of the things about the whole classical conceptions of land and rent and interest and so on is, of course, that classical political economy always looked down on things like this, like interest and rent, because it saw it as unearned income, isn’t it?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, I could have a whole hour on that, but I want to follow up with some charts on the racial element of this. We’ve talked about how the volume of debt is too large to be paid, but I want to say there’s another aspect of debt, and if you could show the racial, that’s right, that chart is very interesting.

One of the results of debt is to create a bifurcated economy, and that means that we’re in a kind of apartheid economy. We’re in a financial apartheid economy. 10% of the population owns over 75% of the stocks and bonds in the population, and they’re almost entirely a white population. We’ve talked about mortgage debt being 80% of the overall debt burden. I want to show what has happened long before the chart begins in 2002.

I want to begin in 1945 at the end of World War II. That’s really when the houses had not been built during the Depression because people, there wasn’t a market for them. They weren’t being built during World War II because all of the raw materials were going to the war effort, and debt for the whole economy was very, very low debt in 1945 because there was nothing to borrow money for. You couldn’t borrow money to consume because everything was rationed anyway.

But finally, they began to make loans, and what had spurred the American takeoff and that of other countries. All countries of Europe, America, and elsewhere were rebuilding after the war, and most of this rebuilding was rebuilding for housing. That was when the great housing was taking place. Here in Queens, you had major developers, not only Trump’s father, but all the famous experiments and group housing were made.

There was only one thing. White people were able to buy houses for maybe $10,000 was a typical price of a house that now costs a million dollars. The problem is that banks would only, in order to buy a house, you had to take out a mortgage. Nobody has enough money to buy the whole value of a house, and if wages were maybe $3,000 or $4,000 a year back in 1945, you couldn’t even buy a $10,000 house. Nobody had that. You had to go to the banks. Banks, until about 2000, 2001, would only make mortgage loans almost entirely to white people, unless you were a very, very wealthy black person or a Hispanic.

What you created was a bifurcated society. The people who bought the houses in 1945—they returned from the war. They took civilian jobs. They bought a house, and many of them died of old age, but they left the houses to the children. And you had one generation after another generation of white people leaving the house to the children, leaving them enough inheritance to have a house of their own and an education of their own. So what you had was a home owning, educated white class, but this was not available to non-whites in this country. So what’s the depth of the restriction of credit to the prime human beings, not to the unprimed borrowers? We’re talking about a pretty racist policy. It was very responsible for the fact that you’ve had now 75 years—well, longer than that, 75 years since World War II—you have a disenfranchised, non-white class in the United States of hereditary homeowners who can get into college because their parents and grandparents went to an Ivy League university. And there’s a monopoly of housing and education and wealth at the top of the economic pyramid, and the rest of the economy is essentially disenfranchised as if we’re in our own financialized apartheid economy.

RADHIKA DESAI: Yes, and there’s a couple of other points. By the way, in this chart, I should just explain that the top line here is essentially showing the homeownership rates, that is about 75 percent, of non-Hispanic whites in the United States. The red line, which is at the bottom here, is of black people alone in the United States, and then the green line is of Hispanics of any race in the United States. So that presumably includes, for example, if you were a relatively white Hispanic, and they do a little bit better. But you can see that the rate of ownership of black people from the early 2000s till today has really not budged. If anything, it’s slightly worse today than it used to be back then, and became considerably worse just before the pandemic, reaching a very low level of below, like around 40 percent, in fact. So anyway, that’s the thing.

But in addition to these things, the kind of financialized economy in which we live, increasingly owning of houses and land, etc., does not necessarily, because of mortgages, the ownership of land or houses does not necessarily confer on you any privilege, because homeowners find that they are paying interest to banks, and even landlords typically are highly leveraged, so the bulk of what they are collecting in rent actually ends up as interest to banks. So in a certain sense, what we are trying to say is that the Federal Reserve has engineered an economy in which not only profits and wages have become essentially in hock to pay interest, are used to pay interest, but so is rent. So that interest has become sort of the prime form of income, at the top of the income pyramid, so to speak.

And this is a result of changes also in the tax structure. So for example, in the U.S. taxation system, earnings from interest and rent are treated a lot more softly, a lot more favorably than our earnings from work. This is a huge problem.

MICHAEL HUDSON: That sort of goes back to the value theory that I think requires a separate discussion altogether, because it’s so fundamental. The whole idea of classical economics and the free market was a market to be free from rent, rent being unearned income. Rent is what landlords make in their sleep. Rent is not created by labor, and most people don’t realize what’s called the labor theory of value that is based on Ricardo and Marx and the whole 19th century. The idea was to separate value, which is created by labor, from economic rent, which is created by hereditary, by privilege, by property ownership, by owner, by banking, and by monopolists, and by landlords who make their money, economic rent, by owning a rental property, or by lending money and making interest, or by having a company, a monopoly. And you just raise prices, and much of the inflation, as Radhika mentioned at the beginning of the talk, they call it profit inflation, meaning a company just decides, let’s raise the price of drugs.

For instance, my wife is on an employer, United Healthcare plan. The price that she has to pay, local drugstores went up quintupled on January 1st, because the healthcare insurer said, we can make money by quintupling the price. Drug companies have been raising the prices all across the board, not by producing more, not because their costs have gone up, which would be, ultimately, the cost would be a cost of production, labor, and materials, but simply because they’ve become a monopoly. And the Democratic Party has always been the great protector of monopolies, because they’re campaign contributors. And if you look at who heads the health committees and the others in Congress, related committees in Congress, their campaign contributors come from the pharmaceutical and drug industry. So you have the governments representing their campaign contributors, the military and state department desks at the Senate and House are subsidized and paid for by the military industrial complex, the health departments from the drug companies, and so on and so forth.

So we’re that part of the problem of what has made America a failed economy. And it’s a failed economy because of the austerity that this debt apartheid has created.

RADHIKA DESAI: And we should probably soon shift to talking about solutions. But let me just add a small point to what you were saying, which is that, of course, if you look at the US economy today, you will see that over the neoliberal period, what has happened is that it has become dominated, of course, by the financial sector, the so-called FIRE sector, finance, insurance, and real estate. And on top of that, if you look at what are the other sectors of the US economy, which are really important and lucrative, you will see that they are the military industrial complex, they are the big pharma, and they are information and communications technology.

And in pretty well all of these cases, these sectors are characterized by a high degree of monopoly, a high degree of rent-seeking in the sense that a military industrial complex, for example, essentially relies on vast government contracts, which are risk-free in which they get to mark up costs as much as they like. And big pharma and information and communications technology rely on intellectual property rights in order to secure their monopoly.

So in all of these ways, this has created an economy which is very undynamic, it is not very efficient, but at the same time, it is very lucrative for those who own it, which of course puts an added burden on ordinary Americans.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, one of the problems of it being undynamic is you’re having a decline in office space, in commercial real estate. We’ve been talking about homeownership rates and how unfair that is, but you remember back in 2008 when there was the property price crash, you had what was called “jingle mail”. You would have buyers, especially in Nevada and Florida, where there was a huge run-up in housing prices, they’d say, okay, I owe $500,000 for this house, but now the house just like it next door is selling for $300,000. I’ll just mail back the keys to the bank and say, okay, I’m defaulting, you can have the house, I’m just not going to pay, I’m going to take out a new loan and buy the house next door.

Well, that phenomenon is now happening for businesses. Apparently [only] 40% of the US commercial properties are occupied. In other words, since COVID, and most of all, since the economy began to shrink as a result of this debt deflation, businesses have been going out of business. Even those who are in business, you have people working from home. Now, if you have the average occupancy rate of buildings being only 40%, how is the owner going to have the money to pay for the bank?

Well, because the banks have lent almost 100% of the value of the building to the homeowner who’s willing to pay all of the rents as interest, rent is for paying interest, that’s the basic motto. What they want is the capital gain in the price of the building. They realize they’re not going to be a capital gain. This was all fictitious capital, it’s going down, we’re mailing our keys back to the bank and we’re walking away from the building.

This year and next year, there is such an enormous trillions of dollars of commercial real estate falling due, not only here, but in England and other countries, that the banks are all of a sudden going to be left with mortgages that are unpaid. Against these mortgages, they have liabilities to their depositors, to their bondholders, and most of all, they want to pay millions of dollars to the, I think Jamie, the head of Chase Manhattan, gets $29 million a year for running a company that’s gone bankrupt and is kept alive because he gives some of that $29 million to the politicians who continue to appoint Federal Reserve people who will bail them out. That’s what you call a circular flow.

What are you going to do when all of a sudden the banks should be going under? Well, normally, if they’ve made a bad loan, somebody has to suffer. Who’s going to suffer? As Bill Clinton said when he was told you have to do what Alan Greenspan says and support the banks, Clinton said, oh, it’s all about the bondholders. In 2009, when Obama came in and decided to bail out the banks, Sheila Baer, the head of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, said, wait a minute, we have a crooked, incompetent bank. There’s one bank in America that’s more crooked than all the others and more incompetent. That’s First National City Bank. Let’s take it over. Let’s make it a public bank. You can’t let this bank destroy the whole economy by being so greedy that it makes loans way in excess of the value of property and keeps expecting to be bailed out so it can make more interest and pay its officers more. Let’s drive it under. And Obama and his Treasury Secretary, Tim [Geithner], said it’s all about the bondholders who own the bank.

So the question is, what will the banks do when all these mortgage loans go under? Well, wipe out the stockholders. But the bondholders are the wealthiest 1% of the population. They’re the ones who own most of the bank bonds. Who do you think the government is going to support? Is it going to support the economy or the stockholders or the 1%? That really is the way in which you should think about an economy being an apartheid economy, not simply ethnically and racially, but financially. That’s the real apartheid between creditors and debtors that I think all of our shows are examining from different perspectives.

RADHIKA DESAI: Well, I’d just like to add a couple of points to what you were saying, Michael. This is very interesting because if you look at commercial real estate, there’s no doubt for the last many months there have been headlines about how there is a collapse of commercial real estate prices. It’s coming. In fact, it’s already happening. As Michael says, the fall in the value of commercial real estate is already ongoing from what we read in the financial press. The really big prestige buildings may not be affected, but the next layer and down, all these buildings will be affected. Everybody who has walked around a big city in North America or for that matter elsewhere in Europe will see that commercial space is essentially going down. So many are boarded up. So many are empty and so on.

And according to one measure, about 10% of US bank assets actually rely on the value of commercial real estate. Now, Michael asks, you know, when the crisis comes, well, the crisis is already here. So who is the Federal Reserve going to help? But you know what, I’m not even sure. And the US government, who are they going to help? Who are US authorities going to help? I’m not even sure they’re going to be able to help them because the fact is that as the value of these assets decline, banks already have to report them if they are publicly listed on an ongoing basis, which means that their shares will already go down. And there is no doubt that a crash will come. And when it comes, yes, the Federal Reserve will once again, as you saw with the Silicon Valley Bank, essentially, in fact, there was another point that I wanted to make there. Essentially, Ms. Yellen stepped forward and said, we are going to guarantee all depositors, even if their deposits are higher than $250,000.

Now, you might think that this is somehow a very democratic thing. But on the contrary, if you look at what kind of bank Silicon Valley Bank was, essentially, it was like a club in which a select group of rich people who are all connected with one another lent each other vast quantities of money.

Now, what does lending mean? It means that I go to my friend and, you know, Silicon Valley Bank and say, you know, please give me $5 million. I’m going to have a startup. You don’t even look at whether my startup is worth supporting. You just say, okay, I’ll give you, I’m going to show a deposit of $5 million in your account. These are the deposits that Ms. Yellen was protecting.

This is not even the money that they have deposited in the bank. This is money that is in a deposit in my name because it has been lent to me. So, if you think about just how huge is the boondoggle that is protecting the interests of the tiny minority of the very wealthy, I hope in this program we’ve given you some idea of the lengths to which US authorities have gone to protect the wealth of this minority. And in our next show, maybe what we’ll do is we are going to devote it entirely to talking about what needs to happen if we are going to move away from this kind of economy.

MICHAEL HUDSON: That’s a good way to end it. There’s so much that it’s leading into. And the last thing that the Federal Reserve wants is for—what if banks reported the actual market value of their assets? When you have a balance sheet, assets and liabilities, they’re holding the assets at the price that they made the loan for, say $100 million for a building. But what if they reported their assets as only $40 million for the building? You would have bank assets here and the liabilities here. They’d look just like most people in America. 50% of Americans don’t have any assets, but they have a big debt. That’s an interesting bar chart to show, assets, liabilities. And you can look at it by income group.

The Federal Reserve does not produce believable statistics on debt as a proportion of income. If you look at the Federal Reserve statistics of debt to income by percentile, 10%, 20%, nothing has changed in the last 50 years. Nobody’s run into debt at all. Because they say, let’s assume that debt is constant for the last half century. The statistics are fictitious. And they’re fictitious because that protects the fact that most of this, what passes as bank capital is fictitious. I mean, we’re in a fictitious economy. It’s sort of like trying to read about international affairs in the New York Times. That’s about as realistic as the Federal Reserve statistics are.

RADHIKA DESAI: Exactly. I mean, it’s basically the rich people of the United States and the big financial institutions of the U.S. are in a situation in which, you know, they make a bad investment, they make a loss and they go, oops. And then the Federal Reserve, which is their sugar daddy, essentially comes and makes good all their losses. It gives them more money to plug the holes in their balance sheets that they have themselves created out of their own greed and misjudgment and bad judgment. So there we have it. It’s this kind of economy that, unfortunately, the United States is laden down with today. And so the question naturally arises, what kind of economy do Americans need in its place?

MICHAEL HUDSON: I want to add one point out there. The important thing is that these rich people who are not paying their debts do not have to pay penalty rates. The large businessmen who owe debts don’t pay penalty rates. You know that if you’re a family and you’re running a credit card debt, if you miss a payment in your electric bill or anywhere, your rate goes up from 19 percent to 30 percent or more. That’s not the case. If you’re rich people, there’s one set of interest rates and penalties for 99 percent of the population, another set for the wealthiest 1 to 10 percent of the population, and you’re not in it.

RADHIKA DESAI: And that’s what we call financial apartheid. So I think with that, Michael and I will say goodbye and hope to see you in a couple of weeks and we’ll talk about what kind of economy we need instead. Thanks very much for joining us and see you in a couple of weeks. Bye-bye.

The post Debt Makes the World Go Around first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Comparing Feudal to Financial

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Sat, 06/01/2024 - 11:32pm in

Tags 

Interviews

Hudson interview with Robinson Erhardt, September 26, 2023.
Michael Hudson: Neoliberalism, Industrial Capitalism, and the Rise of Debt | Robinson’s Podcast #180,

Robinson: I’m from Chicago, and when I saw that you went to the University of Chicago Lab School, which I know quite well, and then the University of Chicago, which I also know quite well—and when the Chicago School of Economics was promoting the free market and probably in its heyday….I immediately found myself wondering: When you’re in this environment, how did you come to believe that what was ostensibly a libertarian ideology was in fact becoming a tool for financial interests to manipulate the government and cheat the 99%?

Michael: I was there from 1955 to 1959. I never knew anything at all about the economics department; I didn’t know anybody there. On one occasion, I met somebody at a party who was in the business school and he was very awkward. Some girl asked for her phone number—and you could see she didn’t like him—and she gave it to him. And then, this was I think a Deutsch-Tisch, German table. So I knew him from the German group there, and my degree was in Germanic history and philology actually. He said, “That girl was really stupid, so attractive, but so stupid, that she didn’t even know her phone number.” I said, “What do you mean?” She said, well, that was the phone number of the fire department. He didn’t get it, but he was being set up.

That was my first introduction to how free market economists think. They take everything on the surface. There’s no understanding of the structure and back of it all. But I never knew anybody from the business school. My interest certainly was not in Chicago economics. The reason I took German was because the German teachers were in charge of all sorts of other departments. Harry Yolas was in charge of the history of culture department. And that really was what I wanted to study. History of culture enabled me to take any course I wanted, cafeteria style. So I was taking art history and I was studying music at DePaul University in Roosevelt simultaneously. And Germans were in charge of the comparative literature department. So that just meant I could take everything cafeteria style basically. And my contacts were largely with humanities professors, literature professors, historians. That was what I was studying. Nothing about economics. I never had any idea at all of studying economics until I came to New York in 1960 and 61.

Robinson: That was a better and a funnier answer than I’d bargained for. So was it then your time at NYU that opened you up to the alternatives to praising the free market without looking at a deeper level?

Michael: No, they didn’t discuss free market either. We were told some I had one of the stupidest professors I’d ever had, Stephen Rousseas, who was teaching monetary theory and he was just sort of a neoclassical neoliberal and everything he said was wrong. I got a C plus in the money and banking course because the question was supposed to be about Hyman Minsky who at that time was not known what he later became known for modern monetary theory. But this was in 1963 when he’d written something about savings banks actually aggravating the financial cycle because his theory was that savings banks put some of their money, their savings, into commercial banks. And his theory, abstractly enough, was that the commercial banks would lend out into the regular economy, personal loans, mortgage loans, et cetera. What neither Minsky nor the professor knew was that I worked for the central bank for the savings banks, the savings banks trust company for three years from 1961 to 64, and all of the New York state savings banks kept all of their reserves in the savings banks trust company, which invested it only in bonds, including World Bank bonds, government bonds, but didn’t make any loans at all into the general economy. That wasn’t what it was set up for. So to think that, yes, here’s a saving, a commercial bank, it must act like the other commercial banks—that’s called correlation without causality. And Rousseas said that I didn’t understand the theory and that reality had nothing to do with theory—that I was there to learn theory, not reality. And that was my introduction to magnate monetary theory.

The good thing about NYU was it didn’t want my brain. All it really wanted was my money to pay for the tuition. I tried to take all 20 courses in the one semester, but they were very hypocritical and insisted that I couldn’t understand, that the understanding was slow and would take, you know, one year for the MA and two years for the PhD, not realizing that you can compress nothing into nothing, you know, three years into nothing. So basically, I got my degree as a union part because at that time I was working first in the savings banks and then in 1964 in December on at Chase Manhattan. Hmm.

Robinson: Well, one question that I wanted to ask before we get to the meat of your writing and particularly your book, The Destiny of Civilization, is how you think of or define debt and debt inflation. And since debt is so vital to what we’ll discuss, I thought it would be a good idea to determine to what extent this is a term of art for an economist that has more nuances than it does in our colloquial usage?

Michael: I don’t think I’ve ever used the term debt inflation. What does it mean?

Robinson: Well, that’s why I was asking you, but I think it’s in the book, but debt inflation is the increase of debt over time.

Michael: I think that I call that the exponential growth of debt at compound interest. I thought we were going to talk about Killing the Host. It’s okay if we don’t. But in Killing the Host, I have a whole chapter on compound interest. The volume of debt multiplies simply by mathematical principles of compound interest, not by any relationship to productivity or the ability to pay, or the real economy. The financial system of credit and debt is imposed on the economy of production and consumption, but does not reflect the relations of production and consumption, profits and wages and earnings and the ability to pay. It merely intrudes upon them. And the exponential growth of debt at compound interest always tends to exceed the economy’s ability to grow through national income, GDP, or the ability to pay, which goes up and down, whereas compound interest does not have a downturn, it just goes upward steadily.

And one of the reasons that economies turn down is because the debt overhead grows so much that it deflates. I talk about debt deflation, not debt inflation. And the term I use again and again is debt deflation. And that is that paying creditors, paying debts to the financial sector removes purchasing power from the consumer spending and from corporate spending on industrial capital formation. So we have debt deflation, there’s credit asset price inflation, very often debt finance, but asset price inflation is achieved at the cost of debt deflation.

Robinson: Is this concept of debt deflation and credit inflation, what contributed or something that contributed to the housing market crash a decade or so ago?

Michael: Yes. And in fact, when I was at the savings bank trust company, my job was to trace deposits and mortgages because savings banks were supposed to lend all of their money out to mortgages in a circular flow. Well, the deposit trend for each bank would be a zigzag. It would jump every three months when interest on the accounts was credited. Obviously, people weren’t really increasing their savings very much, but the increase came just from the accrual of interest that banks would pay out of the mortgage interest that they charged on the loans that they made to the home buyers.

So I realized that as the volume of savings banks increase, assets increase, they were going to recycle it, lend it out, yet more mortgage it. And politically, the savings banks were advocating more and more deregulation so they could make more and more mortgage loans. They wanted to loan outside of New York State. When I got married, my wife and her family had been depositing at a local savings bank for over 20 years. And you’d think that I would have qualified for getting a loan. But the bank said, no, we can make more money by lending to Florida, where interest rates are deregulated and the demand is, so we’re not really lending the New York City people anymore to our depositors. So I thought, well, there goes the whole idea of mutual savings banks. There’s something mutual there. It’s mutually antagonistic savings banks. And I ended up getting the mortgage in Chase Manhattan, instead, since I was working there, it was fairly easy.

So you have the exponential growth of debt, recycled into more and more loans and the mortgage market. And in the 60s, when I was watching how the savings banks and the commercial bank market worked, there was a rule of thumb by bankers. The mortgage loan that you would give out to borrowers couldn’t absorb more than 25% of the borrower’s income. And this would be for a loan that was repayable over 30 years, self-amortizing. And there had to be at least a 10%, preferably a 30% deposit down payment so that you knew that the bank would be able to be repaid. Well, the banks made more and more money and the commercial banks, just like the savings banks, ended up making 80 percent of commercial bank loans in the United States, Britain, and other countries are mortgage loan.

The commercial banks then during the Reagan era, raided and essentially emptied out—they merged with the savings banks, took all the money, didn’t pay the depositors any of the supposedly gains that the depositors made. They stole. They stole all the savings of New York savings banks. Sheila Bair explained some of the details of just how this was done from Wall Street’s aim to me one day, but I was watching it happen while I was even at the savings banks. Most of the directors of the savings banks were people who deposited in the savings banks. Some were plumbers, some were restaurant owners. They weren’t financially sophisticated enough.

And Sheila Bair said, well, now we’re going to increase the professional management and the savings of the savings banks. What they did was they closed down the savings banks and the poor areas, areas with minorities lived or the low income areas. It was just a total travesty of the whole thing. But at any rate, for your question, yes, the commercial banks loosen the terms of mortgage loans so that by 2008, when the crisis came, you could buy a loan with zero down payment. And actually, you would borrow more than the value of the house, typically 101 or 102%. So you’d have enough money over the payment for the house with no money, you could afford to have it painted and pay for the insurance dots and the brokerage fee and the other things. And the mortgage, instead of being limited to 25% of your income, went all the way up to 43% of the income. So today you have the Fannie Mae, the government mortgage insurance agency, guaranteeing mortgages that no bank will lose any money on a mortgage as long as it doesn’t absorb more than 43% of the borrower’s income. And in the United States, now housing costs are about 40% of the income.

Another problem in 2008, in addition to the low down payment, in addition to the increase in income that absorbed, there were false appraisals of the buildings. They used crooked appraisers because then you could lend more money. And the fourth factor was, you would have no guarantee that the buyer had any income at all. The banks would work would conspire with the brokerage companies to make up a fictitious income statement to pretend that the buyer could afford it, even though they had no job, even if they were making no income, they would falsify the price of the house. And then they would look for a sucker. And the biggest suckers, I guess as always, were the Germans, the local state German savings banks. I’m told today Germany thinks that Russia or Ukraine blew up the Nord Stream lines, you know, that was the kind of mentality. Never question an American. American says that it’s got to be right. They bought all the junk, were broke.

Wall Street would bribe pension funds to buy these package mortgages. And basically the mortgages were junk mortgages. And that’s why the newspapers, even before 2008, were using the term “junk mortgages” and “ninja borrowers”. So yes, it was the deregulation that led to the mortgage crash. As my UMKC colleague Bill Black described, this was basically criminal fraud. And Bill Black had been in charge of prosecuting the savings and loan fraud in the 1980s. And what happened under Greenspan was the much greater commercial banking fraud that nobody went to jail, but Obama punished the victims. He punished the victims of the junk mortgages. He evicted 8 million American families so that they would default, creating a bonanza of purchase of buying distress sale buildings and turning America from a homeowner’s economy into a rental economy. Homeownership rates plunged as a result of the crisis and that was the objective and remains the objective of the Democratic Party today, to replace homeownership with a rentier society, a landlord society, to sort of roll back the economy so that it looks like it did in Europe before the 19th century. It’s the kind of neo-feudalist.

Robinson: Yeah. Well, that was very helpful. I think that the story points to a concept that we’ll get to shortly, and that’s the financialization of the economy. But before we get there. I think that was really helpful because I find it very useful to pin down key concepts at the beginning of these conversations. And you just mentioned the rentier society. And the other concept that I wanted to pin down was rent. And so how does rent differ in principle from other forms of income like profit or wages?

Michael: The entire focus of classical political economies from Adam Smith, the Ricardo and Malta, John Stuart Mill to Marx, the Thorstein Veblen was a value in price theory. They realized that not all prices for goods and services, or for assets, actually had cost value, that rent was the excess of the price over and above the actual cost of production. It was imposed on the economy, just like debt and finances imposed on the economy, property ownership in the form of a hereditary landlord class. The heirs of the Nordic Northmen who conquered England, who conquered France, and assigned themselves land rent were basically for 800 years burdening the economy with land rent. The entire political focus of classical economics was to get rid of the fact that there was a landlord class that anybody who occupied a building or lived in it or owned it had to pay rent to this hereditary landlord class that didn’t play any productive role at all that made money in their sleep.

That’s the terminology John Stuart Mill used to describe the landlord. A landlord is a rent recipient who makes money in his sleep without working. So rent is a payment to either a landlord or a monopolist or to a mineral miner, to an oil company, or to a banker in a financial institution, that doesn’t play any role in production at all. Well, if you have a class of rentiers, of landlords and monopolists, whose price does not reflect any necessary cost to production, that’s economic rent. And more and more, what is called GDP or national income, does not take the form of wages and profits made by producing goods and services by industrial companies, it takes a form of economic rent—Mainly land rent, most of the increase in the cost of housing and commercial property in the United States, the rising site value of the land that’s inflated by credit, whatever a bank will lend defines the price.

What they mean by profit inflation is when a company, a monopoly, will decide simply to raise prices because there’s no competition, nothing to stop it. So this is reported as profits, but it’s really rent. The problem is that since about 1890, really for the last 130 years, the economic statistics have stopped recording rent. The landlords fought back, and the bankers backed the landlords in fighting back. The anti-classical, anti-regulatory, anti-government approached economics that there is no such thing as unearned income. I give all of the citations from John Bates Clark and other people in my book, Going the Hope, but there’s the denial in modern neoclassical economics that all income is earned, all wealth is earned, and if somebody’s a billionaire, they’ve made it by earning it, by playing a productive role in the economy. There’s no concept in the national income accounts of rentier income. Everything is counted as profit or providing a service. For instance, you may wonder why, if you look at the statistics, you find people falling behind in their credit card accounts, and their credit card interest goes up from the normal 19 to 23 percent interest charge to over 30 percent. And if you want to know where did this increase out of the national income account treat these penalties.

Credit card companies are making more money on penalties than they’re actually making an interest. Well, all of that is counted in the national income accounts under providing financial services. It’s a service when you increase the penalty on depositors. This is the kind of grey area you get when they won’t acknowledge that the phenomenon of rent is unearned income whose payment becomes a cost of living and a cost of doing business and a cost to companies that have to pay labor to pay various forms of economic rent, but it’s not part of the production. So the statement that American GDP is growing overlooks the fact that the actual product is tapering off or shrinking. All this growth is from the wealthiest 10% that are making their money through rent extraction. It’s an extraction activity, a zero-sum activity. The money that the financial sector or the landlord or the monopolist gets is not adding to the product. It’s a transfer payment from the consumer or the renter or the debtor to the rentier at the top. Our economic statistics pretend to be empirical, but they are not describing how the world really works at all. They’re describing a kind of parallel universe.

Robinson: Hmm. Well, hopefully I don’t have the numbers wrong, but I believe that a few minutes ago you said that in much of the 20th century, the structure of the economy in the United States was shifting back to a mode from before the 18th century and earlier. And this of course suggests that something else was going on in the 19th century when the Western world was also still capitalist. And people typically use the word capitalism, I think, as if it’s a univocal concept.

Michael: The word capitalism came from the German Werner Sombart.

Robinson: I don’t know if this stems from the origin of the word where it was just meant to reflect that some take capital from others or that some-

Michael: Capital was used, but nobody turned the idea of capital into capitalism.

Robinson: My point though is that you distinguish a variety of versions of capitalism that are not equal and I think the right place for us to start is with industrial capitalism. So what was the system and what was its purpose, if it can be said to have one?

Michael: It was really Marx that described how capitalism was basically different from feudalism and from the ancient mode of production. Mark said every era has its own form of creating a surplus ultimately from labor. In feudalism, you serfed them. The serfs were tied to the land. They had to turn over the crop to the landowner, to the local lord. The ancient mode of production was slavery and usury. But the capitalist mode of production was free labor. Labor could work and live wherever it wanted. It wasn’t tied to the land. In fact, it was driven off the land into the cities to seek employment as wage labor. A

And the industrial capitalists differed from the land the landowners and aristocracy, who were the basics of feudalism, because the industrialists employed wage labor to produce a product. The industrial capitalists obtained the money to employ labor, buy capital, buy a factory in order to produce the goods, to buy machinery, to buy the fuels to run the machinery. He would organize the economics of production to produce goods that he would serve at a higher price than it cost to employ labor and buy the raw materials and that bought the production.

So Marx said that all forms of exploiting labor were in one sense or another, exploitative. Slavery of antiquity exploited labor by just giving it the bare minimum. Feudalism exploited labor by just tying it to the land, taking what it produced. And this was purely exploitative. Capitalism exploited labor in the sense that, yes, the capitalist made a profit by employing labor, but the capitalist, unlike the landlord and unlike the slave owner, actually played a productive role in organizing production. The capitalist organized industry and made possible growth. And as the American economists pointed out, especially in the 19th century, they said an intelligent capitalist is going to realize that high wage labor is more productive than low wage labor. So the intelligent capitalist is going to do two things.

Number one, he’s going to pay labor enough to be healthier, to be well fed, well clothed and well educated so that labor’s living standards will be uplifted in capitalism instead of the feudal, rentier mentality, to pay them as little as possible and take all the profit. The capitalist had to be part of an expansion, but also the capitalist didn’t want to have to pay for many of the costs that labor had. So the capitalist wanted an increasing role of government. Outside of England, the capitalists wanted industrial tariff protection so that the prices would be high enough so that domestic industrialists could afford to make the capital investment in plant equipment to rival that of England. That’s what Germany did. That’s what America did. Protectionism.

Secondly, they wanted the government to bear as many of what are now called the external costs of production as possible. As much of the labor’s consumption that the employer did not have to pay should be paid by government. So, England, America, Germany, all the enlightened capitalist economies said, well, we’re going to want government to provide certain basic needs that are not monopolies, like public health. And it was the conservatives, it was the capitalist class fighting for this. In England, it was Benjamin Disraeli that advocated health, health is everything, and advocated public health for England. Another thing would be education.

America was laid out geographically in terms of school districts, where each district would finance its own public education. The government in Europe especially would treat any inherent monopoly as something that the government should produce because the government would provide these services not at cost, but either freely, like education or health care, or at a subsidized rate. So the governments in Europe would have public telephone systems, public communication, public transportation, public water and sewer. Every industry that could be monopolized was held to be appropriately in the government so that it would minimize the cost of living, and by minimizing the cost, the labor, of having to pay for health care and education basic needs, they would minimize the cost of doing business to the employer and to the economy.

So, Marx said the tendency of industrial capitalism—the law of motion of industrial capitalism—was to move towards socialism, to move towards an increasing role of public capital investment. Also, industrial capitalism needed financing. And Marx said that capitalism had revolutionized finance—at least in Germany it was. The old financial system in England, Holland, America was purely predatory. It was not productive. Loans were made for war financing. Ever since the 13th century crusades, it was the Vatican that had taken the lead in organizing a European financial system to finance the crusades and wars, not to play any kind of a productive role.

But Marx said, finally, industrial capitalism has a use of credit that doesn’t involve war, it doesn’t involve corruption, it doesn’t involve making loans to unproductive governments. Industrial capitalism is going to make governments themselves productive. And for that, it’s going to make not only transportation and health care and education of public utility, it’ll make banking in effect the public utility. And that’s what you had in Germany developing up until World War I, so that by the time World War I broke out, even in England, economists wrote articles and economic journals, other publications saying that they worried that Germany was going to win World War I because it had productive banking as a public utility that could finance actual capital investment, whereas British and European banking and American banking simply was asset stripping. It wanted to have profits paid out in dividends to make money for the stockholders and for the bondholders, not to reinvest in expanding production.

So capitalism was basically a transition towards socialism starting with a mixed economy. All of the capitalist economies were mixed economies. But being a mixed economy, the political fight was to take control of the government away from landlords and away from the rentier class and put it in the hands of the industrial class that allied with the wage-earning class together against the landlords. And that was basically what the 1848 revolutions were all about: the labor and capital against the landlords, monopolists, and the banks. And that was the basic political orientation of capitalism.

Well, obviously this entailed: how do you take over the governments of England, France, and other countries that are controlled basically by the House of Lords? And the House of Lords fought against any attempt to tax the land, any attempt to get rid of the protective tariffs that had raised food prices in England from 1815, when the Napoleonic Wars ended. Finally, 1846, when the Corn Laws, the protective tariffs were put aside. They wanted free trade and not protecting other landlords, but bringing the cost of food in England down to the cost of production in the cheapest market, which was basically the United States. So you had the objective of industrial capitalism was to compete with other countries by lowering the cost of production, including the cost of hiring labor, by having governments pick up more and more of the cost of production through public infrastructure investment.

Robinson: Well, let me try to summarize just a little bit before we move on because there was a lot there and you can correct me where and if I’m wrong. So the wealthy’s primary mode of extracting capital in feudal times was essentially slavery and then usury. And actually, it’s worth noting you had a really nice phrase that I’d never heard before in your book and that was “predatory usurious finance”. I’d never heard or read the word usurious before and I liked it. But then after the industrial revolution, the capitalist played a productive role, which he hadn’t before by organizing labor. And then now restricting ourselves to the United States there was a swing back to usury and the rentier economy after World War I. And this leads me to ask what it was that caused this change? Was it the loans you mentioned that had always financed wars, but in this case, it coincided with the rise of the military industrial complex?

Michael: The landlord class saw that industrial capitalism was succeeding in creating governments who look at their task as sponsoring economic growth and raising living standards—meaning the productivity of labor—and in promoting industry at the expense of the rentier class. The landlords, the monopolists, the mining companies and oil extractors, and potential monopolies. The rich people, the dominant rich, all saw this as the dynamic of capitalism and being at their expense.

When the United States created the income tax in 1913, beginning right after 1914, only 1% of Americans had to pay the income tax because you had to have income over a certain level in order to be taxed. Most Americans didn’t make enough to even file an income tax report. And almost everybody who paid an income tax, the rich people, the rich families, either made their money from real estate or in banking and finance or by having some kind of monopoly like John D. Rockefeller in oil or Andrew Carnegie in steel. Banks were looked at as the mother of trust.

Banking in the United States and England always played a reactionary role. The bankers did not help industrial capitalism. Their loyalty was to their class, which was the rentier class. They supported the fight against classical economics. They financed bad universities like Columbia University, which is one of the centers of the rentier class. And Columbia University, which was, I think, at that time, the largest landowner in New York City, did everything it could to fight against land taxation. And they were fighting against Henry George, who was not a good economist, but a popular journalist, who was advocating a land tax. The wealthy families all got together and said, “We don’t want to be productive. It’s really hard to be productive. If you’re a capitalist, you have to organize the production of an industry. You have to advertise, you have to create markets. You have to use your brain. We don’t have brains. We don’t have to have brains. We inherited the money. So we want to run the economy without brains, just purely predatory. It’s our mentality. That’s what we do. That’s where our ancestors gave us all the money by being predatory.”

And there was a hatred of actual enterprise. People had to actually work for a living. It was in a way very much like ancient Rome. If you were an aristocrat, you didn’t want to dirty your hands by actually making money and playing a productive role. You wanted just to live off the fat of the land, to be a parasite. And that’s what the rich want to be. It’s not that they don’t want to be called parasites, but they want to be parasites. They want to call themselves the most productive class that there is, but they’re the most predatory class and they play no role in production. And actually by increasing their gravitation of land rent, they are responsible for deindustrializing the American economy and now the European economy as well. So that…basically that I hope that answers the question.

Robinson: Mm-hmm, it does. And maybe this is where we end up inadvertently returning to the beginning of our conversation and the Chicago school. But in connection to everything we’ve just been discussing, how do you think of the phrase “neoliberal ideology”? And if I’m right to interpret you this way, why is it in fact antithetical to the free market and instead favorable to the wealthy rentier class that we’ve been discussing?

Michael: Well, the word neo very often is antithetical. It was Thorstein Veblen who coined the word neoclassical. And you think, what neoclassical mean? Are they saying what the classical economists said? And what Veblen actually meant was, no, it’s the opposite of classical economics. It was the new mainstream. It was the new official economics. Neo was the status of this anti-classical economics. You used to think of liberals as being for infrastructure investment and social productivity but neoliberal is really neo-feudal or neo-fascist. Neoliberal means the opposite of everything that uh the free market meant the classical economics.

The classical liberals were the physiocrats, Adam Smith on the classical economics. What they wanted to do was free the economy, meaning free markets, from economic rent. They wanted freedom from predatory taxation, from predatory landlord rent, from predatory monopoly rent, from predatory finance. Their neoliberalism was to actually free economies from unnecessary costs of production, unnecessary expenses of labor and industry. But today neoliberal means anti-government. Neoliberal in the 19th century was against governments controlled by the landlords through the House of Lords in England and their counterparts in other countries. Neoliberal today means against productive government, any kind of government regulation. Neoliberal means don’t tax rentier income, tax labor and capital, tax income earned industrially or productively, but don’t tax parasitism because we’re the parasite class and we’re against government taxation, we’re against government regulation. Don’t have anti-monopoly laws, let the monopolists make money. That’s how we make money. We’re the financial class.

So neoliberal means “dismantle the whole edifice of government that’s been put in place over the last two centuries and replace it with what they call a free market”, meaning a market without any active role at all, a market of central planning. Neoliberal means centralized planning shifted away from Washington, and other political capital into the financial center, away from Washington to Wall Street, away from London’s government to the city of London, and in other countries away from their industry towards the international banking. To them a free market is a market where the wealthy people are free to do whatever they want to the renters, to the consumers, to the debtors and exploit them without any government interference with their extraction and predatory behavior.

Robinson: Or to the extent that policy is still done in Washington, it’s heavily influenced by financial and corporate interests.

Michael: Yes, neoliberalism is privatized, but has been socialized for the last few centuries. It privatized healthcare instead of public health. It’s privatizing the educational system through getting rid of public education. And it’s privatized government. That was the Citizens United ruling of the Supreme Court. The campaign donors decide which politicians will have the money to buy the TV time and essentially the pay in the Democratic Party, the Democratic National Committee. The Democrats appoint the heads of every government committee by how much money can you contribute to the Democratic National Committee, which is a group of ultra right-wing rentiers, very much the same people who finance the Republican Party. They’re the same party basically. And they contribute to make sure that labor and industry do not have a representation within the Democratic Party, but only the the rentier class, especially what I call the FIRE sector: finance, insurance, and real estate, along with monopolies in the military and the real estate. That’s the core of the campaign contributors who dominate both the Republican and the Democratic parties, but most blatantly through the Democrats.

Robinson: So do you explicitly then view the two-party system in the United States as something that the rentiers have managed to co-opt into the service of perpetuating their interests?

Michael: Yes. Basically the extremist rentier deregulatory party is the Republican, and the Democrats by pretending to be pro-labor, by pretending to be liberal, keep moving further and further to the right. Their job is to protect the Republican extremists rentiers from any criticism by labor unions or by the left. It’s the Democrats’ job is to detooth any attempt that socialism or really industrial capitalism taking on the dynamic movement that it was evolving into socialism a century ago.

Robinson: Since time is starting to slip away from us, I wanted to give voice to what I think is probably a common criticism of this view. And since half the country—maybe this is an exaggeration believes in trickle-down economics—just why is the concentration of wealth in the hand of rentiers specifically so bad? Is the idea that if this were industrial capitalism, as you’ve already laid out, and the money were going into investments in labor production and organization, then it might not be horrible, but the fact that it’s just going toward pure wealth increases—and as you read in your book, increasing wealth is addictive—but maybe through stock buybacks and land acquisitions, this means that the capital just doesn’t benefit anyone who doesn’t own it.

Michael: Well, obviously it’s not trickling down. It’s being sucked up. The pretence is that the rent extractors are part of the economy. That’s why all of the money they extract is included in the national income accounts and product accounts, the NIPA, as product. The product is taken out of the production and consumption, and the zero sum, zero product activity is all sucked up.

Financial wealth grows exponentially, as I mentioned, by compound interest and by asset price inflation. The recycling of finance into more and more purchase of stocks, bonds, real estate, and rent-extracting resources makes American wage earners pay much more for housing. It used to be that Americans would pay less than 25% of their income for housing. This is in the 1940s and 50s. Now it’s over 40%. All this extra money for housing gets paid to the financial and real estate sector. Basically anybody can buy a house, but you have to pay all of the rent to the banker in order to get the mortgage to buy the house. Your only hope is you can come out with a capital gain, which is really an asset price gain, as the price of that real estate asset is inflated on credit.

The pretence is that, well, don’t all these landlords spend their money back into the economy? Don’t the bankers actually spend money back in? Well, they absolutely, no, they don’t. Bankers do not make loans to build factories or for machinery and other capital investment. What they do is they make loans to corporate raiders who will buy an industrial corporation and then loot it. That’s what private capital does. Private capital will simply take over, do to a company what it did to Toys R Us, Sears, or any of the other companies that are going bankrupt. It’ll buy a company, it’ll do what Samuel Zell did with the Chicago Tribune, and they will begin to pay back the bankers that have lent the money emptying out the employees’ stockholding in the Tribune. So the employees thought they were sharing in the part owners of capital. But being a minority investor does not give you many rights. And so that was looted. The private capital raider will then say, well, let’s just sell some of the assets, the real estate, and then we’ll sell off our buildings and then we’ll lease them back. And then we’ll take the sale price that we get for selling the building and we’ll pay ourselves a special dividend. All of a sudden, they’ll pay themselves a dividend and the company will now have to begin paying rent to the party to whom it sold the building and is then taking a lease back on. Or the capital investor will go to a bank and said, well, look, we’re gonna raise our prices, we’re gonna make the profits. Make us a loan again, and we will promise to pay you this scheduled flow of rents and profits from our real estate and industry and monopolies and chemical companies that are manufacturing companies. And so they’ll take out a loan and then they’ll use the loan proceeds not to increase the production, but to pay themselves a special dividend and all of a sudden the bank has debts to just about everybody that it’s borrowed from, but this money has not been spent.

England right now has been going over the problem of Thames water. If you want to see how the process works look at Thames water that Margaret Thatcher decided to privatize. The buyers of Thames water simply borrowed money and they took all the money that was borrowed, paid themselves the dividend, and did not fix the pipes that are leaking sewage into the water systems, beaches…they didn’t fix the pipes from leaking, they didn’t really put much investment in at all. Their role was to destroy the English water system and loot it and leave it a mess while taking out a huge amount of money pretending to spend the money back into the real economy. So the fact is the money didn’t trickle down from the owners of Thames’ water or from the corporate raiders in the United States. That’s why they’re called raiders. They pay themselves and they then raise prices if they can. As I mentioned earlier, they call that profit inflation and it’s merely monopoly rent power.

The Biden administration right now pretends to be pro labor against monopoly. It has Lisa Kahn trying to fight monopoly, but it’s fighting like hell to prevent Google from being subject to monopoly breakup. It’s really the protector of monopoly. It says one thing and does another. That’s, I guess, politics throughout the world, but it’s practiced to an unprecedented extent in American politics today. And the pretence that the rentiers are productive is the assumption underlying all economic models and all economic statistics, but just because it’s in the statistics doesn’t mean it’s empirical reality. It’s a parallel universe. It’s science fiction.

Robinson: Well, setting the rentiers aside for a moment, is China, which has been booming industrially for some time, and a region I know that you’ve done a lot of writing about, is it an example of an economic situation where the wealth has and does trickle down?

Michael: When people say trickle down, they usually mean trickle down from wealthy people to the rest of the population. There are a lot of billionaires that have emerged in China. I don’t know whether their wealths have actually trickled down. It does through companies like Huawei, which is owned by the employees there. But what has created the wealth in China is largely government spending. Just like the wealth in America was created since the 1930s, very largely. So the assumption that if the economy is getting wealthier, it’s trickling down, misses the point that most of the wealth is created by government capital investment itself, and by governments. And in China, the money creation and central banking is a public utility, unlike the case in the West.

To the extent that China does have billionaires, this is not something that is supposed to be Marxist. You do have people like Jack Ma, who became very wealthy by being an entrepreneur in creating his company. But the government then said, well, you’re going to really have to turn your money over to government to spend much more. The problem is that wealth trickles down from the wealthy Chinese to the extent that the government can lean on them to say, you know, you’ve got to do something with your wealth. Otherwise we’re not going to let you keep it or make the kind of profits you’ve been making in the past. So China’s government has really taken the lead in organizing industry, just as Germany’s government did in a mixed economy. China is a mixed economy. It’s not simply a communist or a totally socialist economy. It’s a mixed economy. That was what made it so much more productive than the Stalinist economy, Soviet Russia. Soviet Russia didn’t really have a private sector, so you didn’t have private entrepreneurs developing new things. The Chinese approach was to let 100 flower bloom. Of course, we’re going to let people see an opportunity to produce something that people need to be productive and make a fortune. It has to be a decent sized fortune. The problem that China’s coping with now is so much wealth in China is made simply on real estate and on real estate financing. How do they avoid the problem? That’s what they’re dealing with daily, right now. But that’s a different problem.

Robinson: So if the wealth of the poor has been produced by government in China, and historically, the same in the United States, how does this point the way to the key reforms that would need to be instituted to get, let’s just restrict ourselves to the United States again, to get us out of the rentier economy?

Michael: Well, if most wealth is created by the public sector… Suppose you’re a predator looking at this and you’re thinking, like the bank robber, why do you rob banks? You say, well, that’s where the money is. If you’re a predator, then you say, well, I can get wealthy by taking what the government has created and putting it into my own hands. I’m going to get wealth by doing what the English did under Margaret Thatcher. I can privatize it all and I can say, have the government give me Thames water, sell it to me for a dollar and I’ll make a billion dollars off it. They can get wealthy the way the kleptocracy did in the Soviet Union after 1991, when it dissolved. They gave oil extraction, electric utilities, private companies, just to individuals. All of this private wealth of Russia came by turning over the wealth that the government had created to privatize it.

Well, America is following the same plan that America imposed on Russia under the kleptocrats. It’s privatizing as much wealth as possible. They’re turning roads into toll roads. In Chicago, for instance, it privatized the sidewalks and the parking meters. So now it’s privatized, the parking spots are way up. In America, already in the 19th century, mining companies and oil companies didn’t have to pay a penny for minerals that they extracted on government lands. And there’s a whole tendency to try to privatize as much of the government as you can right now, culminating in privatizing the Republican and Democratic parties, the political system itself, and essentially shifting all of the wealth away from government into private hands. And once it’s in private hands, the aim of private wealth is not to increase overall public prosperity, but to minimize it. A privatized wealth creates poverty and debt. That’s how it makes its money. By creating poverty and debt, it sucks the income, the economic, the land rent, the monopoly rent, the interest charges…It sucks it all up into the rentier class. So privatization essentially shifts planning itself into the hands of the rentier sectors.

Robinson: But I’d like to talk about some, some specific reforms and how they might be instituted. So one thing, how do you think the tax code would need to be shifted to make sure that rent payments benefit the public rather than just the wealthy?

Michael: That’s what everything that Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, the whole 19th century wrote about. They said the basis of taxes should start with the land tax because the landlords are the people who have been running the economy for the last thousand years. And they don’t play a productive role, just an ownership role. If you tax the increasing land value of real estate, then this rental value right now is paid to the banks. The economy gets more prosperous. The public sector builds parks and museums to improve in the neighborhood. That increases the land value. When New York City extended the subway line along Second Avenue, property prices rose by three times what it actually cost New York City to build the subway. New York City could have had a land tax or unexplained increase in value. They could have taxed this increase in the price of real estate on the lower east side so that New York taxpayers didn’t have to pay for the subway at all. But instead, they increased the property tax on people who had to pay the property taxes. And they raised the cost of taking a subway on the bus to New York. Essentially New York subway riders and tax payers paid to create a huge increase in land prices for the landlords in the Upper East Side. Land tax would have avoided that. The land tax is part of the Economic Rent Act that classical economics advocated.

Oil and minerals were provided by nature. There was no profit reduction there. So appropriating them does entail a cost of paying landlords, paying lawyers, and I think you have to pay a couple of assassins to kill the local people who want to protect the environment. Basically, the mineral wealth should be the patrimony of a country and be taxed instead of sold off to American and European investors who don’t pay a tax because they pretend they don’t make any money from the mining or the oil.

Either you would tax finance, but that’s hard to do because the financial sector is basically a criminogenic sector that avoids that. You have to retake natural monopolies headed by the financial sector into the public domain. You have to make finance and banking a public utility. Ironically, it was the Chicago school in the 1930s. The Chicago plan was indeed to have 100% reserve for commercial banks. You don’t let commercial banks create any more credit because they create credit for predatory reasons, for takeovers, for increasing real estate price inflation. You’ll have the government create the credit. If you do have the local bank saying, “Well, we don’t have enough reserve to make a productive loan. We have a customer, want to build a factory…” the government will then provide a deposit in the bank to enable it within the reserve system to lend out. The government will be the depositor of last resort in all of this. And this Chicago plan was what Dennis Kucinich was advocating in 2016. And that was University of Chicago. That was when they still had an idea of what a free market really was before they were all elbowed out by monitor of the Milton Friedman and Hayek Dan. The taxes are key and retaking rent yielding resources into the public domain.

Robinson: So increased taxes and then shifting their basis. I see how it would lessen the burden on the poor and also increase the wealth of governments, both municipal and national going forward. But beyond freeing up the poor’s capital, I don’t see how it would have an immediate effect on the mountain of debt that the poor have in the form of mortgages or student loans or credit card and medical payments. And this leads me to wonder whether you think there ought to be massive debt write-offs or debt payments made for citizens on the behalf of the government?

Michael: That is the most controversial part of my policy. Yes, if you do not write down the debt, then you cannot re-industrialize the United States. The debt reached such a critical mass that the American economy is going to begin to look more and more like Germany in the 1920s under its reparation debt or England and France under their inter-ally war debts to the United States for which they depended on German reparation to pay.

There’s no way in which this idealized free market economy can be created, a real free market economy, without not only taking away the property rights for rent extraction, but you have to have a clean slate. That was the German economic miracle in 1948. They canceled all of the debts. It was easy for them to do politically because most of the debts in Germany were owed to the former Nazis and nobody wanted them to have the money. Hard to do in the United States. And you’re having Congress even fighting against writing off the student debt. But not only student debt should be written off, but suppose you wrote off all debts. The advantage of writing off debts is not merely to free the debtors from having to pay. It’s if you wipe out the debts, you wipe out the savings of the 1%. It’s the 1% that are the parasites. The 1% are the new feudal lord of the society. You want to wipe out the savings that are the counterpart to these debts.

So there are two parts to the balance sheet. They’re the assets and the liabilities. By wiping out the liabilities of homeowners, you wipe out at the same time all of their debts. Now, obviously you wouldn’t want this to create a new absentee ownership of landlords, make them venerate. So the debts that are written off for the mortgages in the houses would be replaced by a property tax that would absorb not 43% of the homeowner’s income, but let’s say 20, 25%. You would reset the debt in proportion to the ability to pay. So by writing down the debts, the aim of any reform to make an economy resilient has to lie in bringing debts back within the ability to pay. That cannot be done bit by bit. It has to be done in a quantum leap. And that requires certainly an intellectual revolution. And given the fact that the 1% is now highly militarized and vicious, it requires a political revolution as well. And it may be in other countries of Europe, this usually is involved force.

That’s what people don’t want to recognize, that if you view the economy in the way that I viewed it, and the objective of economic reform is to get rid of economic rent, and the economic rent has been siphoning off, transforming wages and industrial profits into interest payments and financial wealth of the creditors into creditor claims on the economy. Now the problem is not like the 19th century. It’s not landlord claims on the economy, it’s hereditary financial claims on the economy. You have to do for finance what the 19th century did for the landlord class. You have to get rid of the property rights of finance that have resulted in privatizing the financial and the banking system in a predatory, unproductive way. And that requires a death cancellation. You can see that most clearly for the global South countries, Latin America, Africa, Southeast Asia. That’s what they’re talking about in de-dollarization today. But it’s also needed for the United States and Europe itself. Without a debt breakdown and a debt cancellation, economics in the West have come to a dead end.

Robinson: Well, all of this to me points to one question that you just briefly mentioned and that’s how can these issues actually be resolved? And so if powerful financial interests in effect control the government as we witness through lobbying efforts all the time, and they would stand to lose tremendously if the government shifted the tax code the way you proposed and writes off debt the way that you’ve proposed, then what chance is there for change? Is the only realistic chance of a violent revolution? I mean, you just said force, but they’re the same thing.

Michael: Right. Well, in the short term, this is not going to happen. But let’s look at 10 or 20 years ahead. Suppose that the BRICS plus China, Asia and its economic revolution that it’s trying to bring to South America and Africa…. Suppose that the United States and the West see that the mixed economy, the socialist economy is growing way ahead technologically living standard, culturally, while they’re shrinking in the United States and Europe, they will have the same choice that Europe had. Somehow Europe, despite being dominated by the feudal landlord class, ended up reforming itself and moving towards socialism up until World War I. It was able to do it in the 19th century. That can happen again in the West. The revolutions after World War I were violent in Europe. Even the 1848 revolution was somewhat violent. The Paris Commune was violent. There will be some violence.

Basically, the United States is at the root of violence. The United States has said is the head of the CIA put it, murder, ink. The University of Chicago free market made it very clear in Chile. They said you cannot have a free market unless you close down every university that teaches economics in Chile and replace it with us. You have to be willing to assassinate and kill every labor union leader. You have to kill every land reformist. You have to kill every university professor that says there is an alternative. You have to kill every progressive. If you’re not willing to kill the intellectual elite of the population, if you’re not able to have a mass murder, such as we worked in Chile, Argentina, and all throughout Latin America, then you’re not going to have a free market, making it free for us to take whatever we want from the economy and smash it to pieces.

Robinson: Well, Michael, you have superbly, concisely, and also I think comprehensively answered all of my questions and we really covered a lot of material. So thank you so much for taking the time and having this conversation with me.

Michael: Well, I can see you prepared very well. You’ve understood my writing and what I’ve been saying. So I’m very happy to have this discussion with you and I look forward to seeing it transcribed.

Photo by Alex Gruber on Unsplash

The post Comparing Feudal to Financial first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Predictions 2024

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Fri, 05/01/2024 - 9:22am in

Tags 

Interviews

Transcript of an interview between Ania and Michael Hudson. The interview took place on December 29, 2023.

ANIA: Hello everyone, welcome back to my channel. It looks like we are live and we are a few seconds before time, so a little bit better than Swiss precision. Today I have for the second time a very, very special guest. Many of you have been anticipating this conversation with Professor Michael Hudson, who is the financial analyst and very distinguished research professor of economics. Someone whose expertise, opinion, knowledge I very much value. And I think as we are coming to the end of 2023, this might be a very important discussion here, very important information from Professor Hudson. So welcome back, Professor Hudson. Thank you so much for finding time for our conversation.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, it’s good to be back, Ania.

ANIA: Thank you. And just to let you know, everyone, all the links to find Professor Hudson are already down below this live stream. You can support his work via Patreon, all the books, there’s a link as well, also his website. All the links are down below. I appreciate you subscribing, liking, sharing, supporting my channel as well. And let’s start with actually Professor Hudson has sent me a very, very informative email. And I want to say thank you officially now to you for sending this to me because of that email, I was able to kind of narrow my question down to you. And if there are any questions from the audience, please put them in the Super Chats.

So in your email, you’ve mentioned that Ukraine’s apartheid state is an apartheid state. And I would like to start with this. Can you explain to the audience what does this really mean to be an apartheid state? And Israel is also an apartheid state.

MICHAEL HUDSON: An apartheid state. Well, that goes back to Nazi Germany in the 1930s. An apartheid state says that only one ethnicity should dominate the state and all other ethnicities should be excluded. As soon as World War II ended, the U.S. military and the intelligence agencies recruited the nationalists and the Nazis who had been working for the Germans against the Russians into the NATO framework as managers and began to prepare for a long-term fight against the Soviet Union. Somehow the end of World War II metamorphosized gradually into really a renewal of what followed World War I, the fight against the Soviet Union. And from the very beginning, for the last 80 years, the United States has sought to fight Russia. Even when Russia stopped being the Soviet Union, it was viewed as having an independent characteristic, an independent policy. And so it used the Nazis to spur a nationalistic, anti-Russian feeling of treating the Russians really as subhumans, denying the Russian-speaking population the retirement income and Social Security and health care and public services. And basically you had the Ukrainians treating the Russians as the Germans had treated the Nazis.

Well, you’re having the same fight now in Israel when Netanyahu and President Biden says there can only be one ethnicity in Israel. There can only be a single state. It’s possible to have a two-state solution. You can have Israel and you can have Palestine, but only Jews will occupy either Israel or Palestine.

The United States mentality, not only for Ukraine and for Israel, but for the whole world economy, is there can only be one economy and one state favoring one group of people. And what you’re seeing in the apartheid state of both Ukraine with its anti-Russian, banning the Russian language, banning Russian books, destroying Russian novels and literature from the libraries, not performing Russian music. All of this is followed by the United States pressing for the Olympic Committee, for instance, not to let Russian athletes join in the Olympics under the flag. The apartheid that you’re seeing in Ukraine is followed by the United States itself, spurring the apartheid state. To the United States, Both Ukraine and Israel are sort of models of what the United States would like to do on a global basis for the entire world economy. There can only be one economy. And basically, it’s a U.S.-NATO-centered economy to which other countries are either supposed to obey and accept the rules or else they’re to be fought against. And so you can look at what’s happening in Israel right now and Ukraine right now as a dress rehearsal on a small scale of the same kind of fight that is occurring in the world economy. Are there going to be two different economies? And are these economies going to be equals democratically? Or is the world economy somehow going to be itself an apartheid state between the United States and NATO on the one hand and the BRICS Plus and the Global South on the other, all in a central unit? That really is what all this fight and maneuvering is about right now in the Mediterranean and the Red Sea and the oil gulf. It’s not only an ethnic apartheid, it’s an apartheid of economic systems, both in Ukraine and Israel and in the kind of order the United States is trying to create.

ANIA: Thank you so much for answering this. And on this note, I would like to ask you two questions following on that. First, do you think the United States will be able to succeed this plan, will be able to be successful with this plan? And will the U.S. be able to keep Western Europe as a U.S. economic, political and military satellite? Yes or no? And if no, what’s going to happen?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, there are really two questions there. For your first question there, what is success? The fight in Israel right now is really a process that’s been going on for 20 years. The United States is backing Israel. And you can look at Israel as being to the United States what Ukraine is. The United States is willing to fight to the last Ukrainian against Russia. It’s willing to fight to the last Israeli against the Muslim states. The United States ever since 9-11 in 2001 has wanted to conquer Iraq, Syria, and most of all, Iran, as well as Libya. In the United States press, all of the discussions of what’s happening in Gaza and Israel today, whenever they talk about Hezbollah or Hamas, the newspapers all put in the qualifying adjective, Iranian-backed Hamas, Iranian-backed Hezbollah. And if Iraqis are trying to fight to drive out the Americans that are stealing the oil from Iraq, it’s the Iranian-backed Iraqis.

This whole fighting that you’re seeing in Israel now, that on the surface seems to be a fight to purify the Israeli state from the non-Jewish population, is part of the American attempt to really conquer the whole Near East and its oil production. To America, the Near East is important because American domination of the world economy for the last hundred years has rested upon its control of oil, along with British Petroleum and the French oil companies. The United States has used oil as controlling energy, and by controlling energy and its pricing, controlling industrial productivity and GDP. GDP, labor productivity, industry, is all a function of energy.

So what the United States is doing is goading Netanyahu to try to provoke the Lebanon Hezbollah into retaliating, so the United States can attack Lebanon, and trying to provoke Iran. It recently assassinated an Iranian leader in Syria, trying to provoke Iran into doing something.

Well, under normal circumstances, when Lebanon or Iran is attacked in the way that the Israelis are attacking now, you’d fight back. That’s the natural tendency. If you’re punched, you’re going to punch back. But this is so obvious that this is what the United States wants Lebanon to do, and wants Iran to do, that they’ve stepped back a month ago, and said, wait a minute, we’re not going to retaliate, just like the United States was trying to goad the Ukrainians to provoke a Russian attack, so that we could begin to bleed Russia, the United States is trying to provoke an attack so that it can finally attack Iran with everything it has.

Well, what has happened for the last month is Iran and Hezbollah and other Muslim groups have talked with each other to try to coordinate what we’re doing, and saying, look, we’re all under attack. We’re not going to let the United States pick us off one by one. Let’s not let the United States divide and conquer us, and first conquer Lebanon, and then conquer Syria, and then reconquer Iraq and drive out the opposition and the liberation fight in Iraq, and then conquer Iran. We’ve got to have a united front, and that’s why Russian ships and Chinese ships have moved into the area, and it’s realized that this fight that seems on the surface to be one between Netanyahu and the Palestinians, is really just a catalyst, a fuse, a trigger for the Near Eastern war that the United States has been planning.

And that brings us to the second part of your question. Will the United States succeed in maintaining control of Europe? Well, the fight in the Near East is very similar to the logic that the United States was fighting with its foreign policy in Europe, beginning in 2022. Its fear was that looking at the world situation from the German and French perspective, the logical policy of Western Europe would be to have a symbiotic trade and investment relationship with Russia and with China. And in this relationship, Germany would import Russian oil, gas, and other raw materials, and it would pay for the imports by exporting industrial goods.

Well, if this scenario had unfolded, the United States really would be pretty much left out. What did it really have to offer Europe? Well, the one thing it had to offer was refraining from blackmailing the German and French political leaders who basically had been nurtured and prepared by the United States State Department and CIA and non-governmental organizations, the National Endowment for Democracy, all to sort of represent U.S.-NATO interests, not the interests of their own countries.

From the United States’ point of view, how do you make Europe part of the U.S. economy, not part of the BRICS economy, not part of the Eurasian economy? Well, Nord Stream took care of that, along with the trade sanctions that the U.S. put in the hands of the German leaders, especially NATO leaders, to impose on the entire European economy. Well, right now, you’re seeing the collapse of the German industry as a result. The BASF, the large German chemical company, has already announced that its new plants are going to be located in China because that’s where it can get the natural gas and the oil, largely from Russia, that it needs technologically for its operations. Just last week, one of the big metal companies in Germany announced it’s closing its doors, it’s laying off its labor force, it cannot produce in Europe anymore. European companies are all closing down, and their choice is either to follow the U.S. directions and say, well, why don’t you move to the United States and put your plants in the United States?

Well, they can’t really put their plants in the United States because the cost of living and doing business is so high in the United States, because it’s a financialized economy, that they can’t make profits. So they’re thinking, well, where are we going to move? We can’t move to Russia because they have sanctions. Do we move to China? Do we move to India? Do we move to Asia? Or do we just continue to close down, and where is our labor force going to go? Germany has a very high productivity, highly trained, highly skilled technical labor force. There are no jobs for it now. They’re being closed down.

The question is, will Germany end up looking like Latvia, losing its population? This labor looks for some countries that want skilled machinists, skilled industrial designers, skilled, basically, industrial workers. Well, all of this is occurring in Asia. It’s not occurring in the United States. It’s not occurring in Europe.

So the question is, at what point will the European government act in the interest of its population? Well, you’re already seeing the European population rejecting the European government, because the European government turns out to be NATO. It doesn’t turn out to be acting in the interests of Germany or France or other European countries, but in the interest of NATO that’s controlled by, basically, an arm of the State Department.

And the question is, how can you bring democracy to Europe? It hasn’t really been democratic in the sense of the United States meddling since World War II. For 80 years, the United States has been financing the political right wing. You’ve all seen the story of the Gladio terrorist operation in Italy that the United States staged to oppose the left-wing Prime Minister Moro, ending with Moro’s assassination by a CIA front. The United States has said, we’re going to treat Western Europe in the same way we treated Chile under Allende. If Europe votes for somebody like Allende, we’re going to put in a European Pinochet and a man like Macron, who’s completely anti-labor and doesn’t represent his constituency, or leaders like Angelina Baerbock, the Green leader in Germany, pro-military leader Olaf Scholz, the Christian Democrat leader. They’re going to put in leaders who reflect the U.S. neoliberal doctrine.

And the real fight is, are you going to somehow make all of continental Europe thatcherized and Reaganized and financialized to privatize its public infrastructure along the lines that have occurred in England, in the United States, and in Chile under Pinochet? This is the great question.

Well, what can the European population do when the political system only permits them, basically, to vote for the leading three parties, not for any real alternative that is trying to say, well, why don’t we join the global majority and be in an economic system of mutual gain, mutual trade, mutual investment? That’s the question. Your question is, can it succeed? It can succeed as long as the United States can prevent democracy in Europe by making NATO the political policy arm of Europe instead of democratically elected politics representing the interest of voters.

ANIA: Thank you, professor. So what is the way out of it for the citizens? Do you think it’s an uprising of the citizens? How? Because I see this. I believe that many countries will be ultimately pulling out from the European Union system. You know, in Poland now, they just signed this agreement because they were opposed to it at first. Now we have a new government that is really in the same… A long story. Anyway, we will have to welcome the migrants, because if we don’t, I forgot the exact amount, how much penalty the country has to pay. Is it daily, I believe? 50,000 euros per day, I believe? Something of that nature. How do you see this ending? Because if those, and we know those leaders, so-called leaders, are already assigned to certain positions, they are most of the time groomed to be in those positions. There is a certain ideology that has to be implemented. How those countries, how those citizens come out of it ultimately?

MICHAEL HUDSON: I don’t think they are going to come out of it. I think that Europe is a lost continent for certainly the next decade. It’s going to take a long time. I don’t think Europe can save itself, because it hasn’t made any attempt to save itself. The European leadership believes that it must depend on the United States for their personal support, and also their personal fortunes, and even their personal freedom. So I don’t think that Europe can save itself.

I do think over the long term, the rest of the 21st century, they’re in salvation, but it won’t come from Europe. It will come from China, Russia, the BRICS Plus, and Eurasia, with the Global South, pursuing an entirely different economic and political agenda. You’re going to have the world dividing into two parts, and we’ve discussed this on, I think, our last show. You’ll have the neoliberal, financialized, privatized, NATO, European, U.S. economy. On the one hand, what Joseph Borrell calls the flowering garden, which is really, the flowers are all wilting, but the flowers have been picked. They’re not really a growing garden anymore. They’ve been picked and are lying on the ground.

ANIA: Poisonous flowers.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Right. And on the other hand, you have the jungle. The jungle is what’s growing. That’s what a jungle does. It grows. So the jungle is going to be Asia, East Asia, South Asia, and its linkages to Africa and Brazil. And the wild card is, of course, who’s going to control the Near East. Now, the alternative to the U.S. neoliberal model is a model of mixed economies. I see China and Russia following pretty much the same model that the whole world was going in prior to World War I.

In the early 20th century, you had American industrial capitalism. You had German industrial capitalism, all with a very active public sector. Both countries relied on government investment in roads, railways, canals, school systems, health systems, to minimize the cost of living, minimize the cost of doing business, and to prevent monopolies from developing that would make money without really producing anything.

All of that ended with World War I. The fight against the Soviet Union became a whole fight against not only socialism, but against industrial capitalism’s own idea of having public infrastructure as the key driver for economies. Well, right now, you’ve seen China take the lead in a country that is using its economic surplus not to make financial wealth, but actual tangible means of production. Railroads, the high-speed trains, roads to drive on, car production, industrial production. And you’re having a mixed economy, with most of all money itself being treated as a public utility, so that the government can decide, what are we going to create money for? We’re going to create money to finance tangible capital investment and employment in real goods and services. Building houses, building office buildings, building the infrastructure, building ports and ships and trains and railroads. That’s what they’re creating money for.

In the United States, the Federal Reserve, and in Europe with its central banks, are creating money basically for financial interests to buy existing industrial companies and infrastructure and close them down. The model for Western Europe is the Thames Water in England, a company that was privatized, and instead of providing clean water and stopping pollution in the sewage system, just uses the money that it gets to pay dividends to the investors without making the investment, and ends up polluting the water and losing a lot of water through leakage, and just being the disaster that you’re seeing in England. Similar stories could be said in the United States.

Let’s look 10 years, more likely 20 years in the future. What is going to happen when Western Europe and the United States see how China, Russia, Iran, and the rest of the BRICS 10 countries are raising their living standards, increasing their productivity? They will be to the West what America was to Europe after World War II. Now the situation is reversed. Now it’s the US and Europe that will look towards Russia and China as the leads of how do we emulate them? How do we get Russian and Chinese products for luxuries? Instead of buying blue jeans, American blue jeans and cigarettes as they did after World War II, they’re going to want to buy Chinese and Russian and Asian and, I hope, Near Eastern products as well.

Obviously, at a certain point, not only the population but business interests will say, well, if we want to make money, we’re going to have to join this expanding economic order instead of staying with the shrinking economic order that we’re seeing in the United States and Europe. Normally, you would think that countries always would act in the interest of their leading business classes, but that hasn’t happened in Europe. It hasn’t happened in the United States, and it is happening in Asia because of the way in which governments are creating a market for business to make profits by expanding the economy rather than by closing it down and gentrifying it.

ANIA: Wow, so you literally took me to the question that I had for you, which is, will the Western Europe ever reunite with Russia in trading? And you were already answering it, but I would like to know at what point you think this will happen?

MICHAEL HUDSON: That is impossible to say because the United States is doing everything it can to fight against it. And the United States cannot compete economically with Europe and Asia. It cannot provide an economic model or an economic system that works better.

What it does have is the power to destroy. Not the power to trade, but the power to destroy. It can mount color revolutions. You just saw last week an attempted color revolution in Serbia. And you’re seeing yet more attempts at color revolutions in Kazakhstan because that produces oil. So Kazakhstan has the curse of oil just as the Near East has the curse of attracting American military attacks. The American policy is not economic rivalry. It’s a regime change, color revolutions, and ultimately the kind of war that you’re seeing in the Mediterranean and Red Sea right now. The United States has 800 military bases around the world, and they’ve been put in place for just such an occasion. This is the time when the United States is finally saying, let’s use all the weapons that we have because we’re almost out of guns. We’re out of tanks. We’re out of ammunition. We’re out of bullets. We’re out of missiles. This is our last chance to fight, to at least if we can control Iran and the Near Eastern oil, we can starve other countries into depending on American control of energy, and on the condition that they not join the BRICS 10, that they join the United States instead of China and Russia, that they break relations with the East and lock themselves into the same dependency on the United States diplomacy that Europe has locked itself into.

So Europe is sort of a dress rehearsal. What’s happened to Germany is a dress rehearsal of what the United States is trying to do to other countries. And of course, the U.S. model is what happened to Russia under President Yeltsin, who was the tool of the neoliberals in the 1990s. Privatize all of this infrastructure that the socialist countries have put in place. If you can privatize it and sell it off, then you can replace infrastructure with low prices with natural monopolies charging very high prices. And if Americans are permitted to create the dollar money on their computers and buy out these companies and turn them into monopolies, then America can somehow live off the monopoly rents that it extracts from the BRICS countries and use these rents to pay for the manufactured goods and the labor-produced goods that these countries are supposed to supply the U.S.-NATO economies with a kind of a class war that is put back in business of the rentier economy in the West and the labor economy, socialist economies in the East.

The question will be, will BRICS in Africa and Brazil and other South American countries be willing to submit to financial colonialism and military colonialism in the same way that 18th and 19th century military colonialism of Europe took place? It’s really the same fight but on a different kind of a chessboard, a financial diplomatic covert chessboard instead of open military conflict.

ANIA: Thank you, professor. Here is a question from the viewer and I would like to ask this question to you. Dr. Hudson, I’m relatively young with not much but ambition and intelligence. Should I stay in the U.S. or if not, where should I move? Much appreciated. Could you answer this, please?

MICHAEL HUDSON: That depends how you want to steer your ambition. What is it that you want to do? Do you just want to make money? Do you want to survive? Do you want to be creative? Is there any talent that you have that you’re interested in? People are best at doing what naturally interests them and they follow it up, whether they’re a musical performer, a dancer, an industrialist, an inventor, an author, an analyst. Everybody has their own particular talents and whatever your talents are, you decide, what field do I want to go into? And then you say, well, okay, if this is what I want to do, this field, where and what part of the world is this field more promising?

Well, you’re very likely to have Americans asking questions like that. And just as Europeans asked this question 200 years ago and decided, well, if they want to be innovative and make money for themselves, they’re going to leave Europe and move to the United States. Well, a lot of Americans are going to think, well, now if we want to be innovative, we’d better move to China, Russia, Iran, and one of the BRICS countries that are following economic growth.

Because no matter what you want to do, whether it’s art or industry or even finance, you’ll do better in a growing economy than a shrinking economy. So you’re going to look at where is the world’s economic growth going to be centered. You can look at the U.S. economy as a failed economy. And the U.S. is a failed state. And you can look at Europe as a failed state because it let itself be run by U.S. neoliberal planners that are treating Europe just like they treated Russia in the 1990s. So wherever you see the growth of what you’re interested in is occurring, that’s where you want to go. And you may very well see a reversal of the whole world immigration movement to the new world. And now they move to the new New World, which is East Asia and Russia, the north.

ANIA: Thank you so much for answering this. I would like to ask you now about the United Nations. What is the purpose of existence of the U.N. anymore?

MICHAEL HUDSON: The purpose is to serve the United States foreign policy. That was built into the United Nations at the beginning by giving the United States veto power. The purpose of the United Nations is not to do any action or support any policy that is vetoed by the United States on the Security Council.

Well, what this means is that the United Nations is a failed institution. It’s a failed state. I remember when it was formed back in 1945 and all of the talk was the Nuremberg trials and the purpose of the United Nations ostensibly was to prevent war and to create an alliance of countries to move against any country that either was Nazi, meaning ethnic Nazism, ethnic superiority or war.

Well, beginning in 1950, the United Nations became the first official declarer of war, namely the Korean War. Russia did not use its veto for that because Stalin wanted to see the war in East Asia, fearing that the United States was going to fight Russia in the west from Europe. Stalin was paranoid about another invasion of Russia from Germany and the old Nazi countries under U.S. NATO move against itself. And so Russia let the United Nations proceed with the war in Korea, and Stalin sort of browbeat Mao into agreeing to support the North Koreans in this.

Well, any thought that the United Nations has a role to play, ended two months ago in October of this year. If the United Nations cannot prevent the ethnic attacks in not only in Ukraine, but in Israel, the the attempt at genocide of the entire Gaza population, as President Netanyahu has explained, the goal is to have an Israel for Israelis free of Palestinians.

Here you have a whole country that is at odds with the ostensible purpose of the United Nations and is breaking all of the rules of war that were supposed to be the rules of the United Nations. What the United Nations lacks is any attempt to enforce penalties on countries that are violating the United Nations Charter. You’ve had the head of the United Nations, Gutierrez, quite rightly, denounce Israel for genocide and denounce what’s happening as genocide. He refused to do that against Ukraine, but it was the same policy. And you have the Pope doing the same thing, denouncing the genocide that’s taking place.

But Stalin said to Churchill at the Yalta meetings in 1944-45, Stalin said, how many divisions does the Pope have? And Churchill said to Stalin, well, you know, you really want the… There are a lot of Catholic countries, you want the church on your side. Stalin said, well, without an army, what can the church do? Well, you can say, without an army, what can the United Nations do? Without an ability to impose economic and political sanctions on the United States and Israel, we’re talking about a partnership here. It’s not just Israel. It’s the United States and Israel in a tandem. It’s the United States that is providing all of the bombs, all of the armaments, all of the money to support Israel. Israel is really very much like Ukraine in its dependency on the United States and also in the corruption of its leadership, the personal political corruption, which is why Netanyahu would be sent to jail as soon as the war ended because he was already being accused of as much of being a criminal as Zelensky in Ukraine. You can think of Netanyahu as Israel’s Zelensky.

Well, if the United [Nations] is powerless to do something here, then what you need is an entirely new international organization, independently from the United Nations. You still need, officially, I guess the Russians and Chinese need to leave somebody in a hotel room in New York just to make sure that they can veto any attempt to have a new Korean War against whoever is America’s enemy of the moment. But you need a new institution that is empowered to actually commit its members to impose military, economic, and political sanctions against countries violating the basic legal rules of war and violating all of the Nuremberg laws that came into being. If you can’t do that, then there is no function at all for the United Nations, and you might as well disband it. It’s obvious that if you even try to reform the United Nations, and I don’t believe it can be reformed, it cannot continue to exist in the United States.

The Golan Heights would be a nice place for it. If it can’t solve the problem in Golan Heights, what’s the point for it to exist? Or it could be in Odessa. That would be a nice place for the United Nations. If it cannot solve the problem there, what’s the point?

There’s no point at all given the American veto power in it, just as America insisted on veto power in the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and any international organization that it joined. If it didn’t have veto power and the power to prevent an organization from pursuing any policy that the United States disagreed with, then it wouldn’t join. The International Criminal Court, International Trade Organization, you can go right down the line.

ANIA: Thank you, Professor. Even though I told you before we started the live stream that we will go about 30 to 40 minutes, I still have two more questions, if that’s okay.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Sure.

ANIA: Thank you. I want to ask you now, for the year 2024, what, in your opinion, will be the biggest change from the monetary financial standpoint? What can we expect?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, you’re trying to have other countries having an alternative to holding their international monetary reserves apart from the dollar. There’s going to be a special kind of money that will be created by the BRICS, and a kind of BRICS bank. This money won’t be dollars and it won’t be euros. It won’t be a currency that you can trade in or buy, like sterling or dollars or euros. It will be a means for central banks to hold mutual claims on each other.

In order to have a monetary system, you have to have a different taxing system, because money and taxes all go together. What gives money its value is the ability of this money [to be used to pay] taxes. You’re going to have to have a synchronism of BRICS members, of monetary tax policy, and also you’re going to have to need their own alternative to the International Monetary Fund, because the International Monetary Fund’s role is to promote austerity in other countries and to force other countries to pay their dollar debts.

The big financial shock is going to be the BRICS countries and the Global South stopping payment on their dollar debts. They’re going to realize that there’s a war on, and in a war you don’t pay debts to the country that’s attacking you. If it’s a colonial war of liberation or a post-colonial war of financial liberation from debt peonage and debt colonization and debt dependency, then you’re going to have essentially a clean slate wiping out the debts to the International Monetary Fund and the general dollar debts that have all been imposed under IMF leadership and under United States leadership as a purely exploitative phenomenon.

These countries will say, these are bad debts. When a bank makes a bad debt, the bank loses money. I’m afraid that the US dollar bank is going to have to absorb the loss. They never should have made loans to countries of Latin America, Africa, and Asian countries that they cannot pay.

Since the United States, just again yesterday on December 28, advised Europe to grab all of Russia’s foreign money, it’s done this as a warning really to Saudi Arabia. It’s telling Saudi Arabia, do you really want to join with the other Muslim countries with all of the money that you saved since 1974, since the oil crisis? All this money, we’ve told you it would be an act of war if you didn’t hold this money in the United States. Well, now we have your money and we’re going to grab it all just like we grabbed Russia’s money, just like we grabbed Venezuela’s money, just like we grabbed Iran’s money, unless you act as an arm of the United States. And so Saudi Arabia is going to have to work with the BRICS countries to move its dollars as rapidly as possible as it can out of the United States and Europe into a safe haven. The fate of the oil countries’ monetary reserves is going to be the key monetary crisis of 2024. Will they be able to achieve freedom from the United States’ grabitization?

ANIA: Thank you so much for this. I want to ask you now, looking back in history, as there is a saying that history repeats itself, if you look at the current reality we are living in, what era in history would you compare it to? And do you think the outcome will be the same?

MICHAEL HUDSON: I can’t think of any real comparison that is a repetition today. I can’t think of any other conflict between a thriving economy and a dead economic system apart from the 19th century flowering of classical political economy. From the French physiocrats, to Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, to Marx and the socialists, they had the same fight. How were they going to free their economies from a parasitic, unnecessary legacy of feudalism, namely the landlord class that burdened the entire economy with land rent? How do you get rid of the landlords? By taxing the rent away. How do you get rid of the monopolies? Essentially, by taking them into the public domain and by socializing the basic needs. And how do you get rid of the worst monopoly, the financial monopoly of credit creation, by making money a public utility?

This was the fight that America and Germany fought so successfully from the late 19th century to the beginning of World War I. And that is the same fight that’s happening today, except instead of fighting against feudalism to create an industrial capitalism that is evolving into socialism, we’re having a geopolitical fight of Eurasia, Russia, China, along with the Global South to be independent of the neo-feudalism of neo-liberal economics done by the United States and NATO.

ANIA: So, you don’t think we will end up in a global war?

MICHAEL HUDSON: The United States is threatening to do that. That’s the one power it has. It can say, well, if we can’t control the world, the world’s not worth surviving. That’s the U.S. attitude. Just as President Putin of Russia said, well, if America destroys Russia in atomic war, who wants to live in a world without Russia? Certainly not the Russians who were destroyed.

So, yes, there is a chance of war and it’s never been higher. It’s the United States that is trying to provoke the war because it has 800 military bases. No other country in the world, no other region of the world has the kind of military bases or the war mentality of wanting to go to war, of wanting an atomic war that the United States leadership has.

That’s what should shock the BRICS Plus countries and the Near Eastern countries into a realization that the United States is threatening them not only with economic parasitism, but with atomic destruction and military destruction. That’s what the war in Israel and Gaza and Lebanon is really all about. It’s about the United States sweeping across the Near East to Iran and grabbing control of all of the oil or simply at the worst case, simply destroying it all, simply bombing Saudi Arabia, so leaving the world entirely dependent on oil from supplies controlled by the United States.

So, yes, as Rosa Luxemburg said a century ago, the choice is between barbarism and socialism. And barbarism is the US NATO today. Socialism is the hopes for what BRICS 10 can become.

ANIA: Professor Hudson, thank you so much for joining me today. I am really, really grateful for your time, honor for your time. And I want to ask you, what can we wish you for the 2024? What would you like to be the wish for 2024?

MICHAEL HUDSON: That people understand what the real war is about and that it’s about what kind of a world we’ll have and really what direction civilization is going in. This is really a civilizational war. It’s not just a military conflict. It’s not just an ethnic conflict. It’s not just the financial rivalry. It’s really a choice of which direction civilization is going in.

And that’s why I wrote my book, The Destiny of Civilization, to explain what the fight is all about.

ANIA: Thank you so much. And that book and many other books you’ll find down below the live stream. There is the link attached already. And the website to Professor Hudson, also his Patreon, where you can support his work. Thank you so much for joining us today, everyone. Thank you for your comments. Thank you for your likes. Thank you for sharing this video. I appreciate you very much. And thank you, Professor Hudson. Hopefully until next time, next year.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, thank you very much, Ania.

Photo by Philip Oroni on Unsplash

The post Predictions 2024 first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Is It Over Yet?

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Tue, 19/12/2023 - 10:32am in

Tags 

Interviews

RADHIKA DESAI: Hello and welcome to the 20th Geopolitical Economy Hour, the show that examines the fast-changing political and geopolitical economy of our time. I’m Radhika Desai.

MICHAEL HUDSON: And I’m Michael Hudson.

RADHIKA DESAI: Well, it’s happening again. Reports of the death of neoliberalism are once again proliferating. Just take a look at the UK Guardian. In the UK Guardian website, there’s a whole series of stories, whether neoliberalism is dying, the rise and fall of neoliberalism. Biden just declared the death of neoliberalism. Is neoliberalism finally over? Is neoliberalism finally dead? Is the neoliberal era over yet? And of course, there are also contrary views. The National Institutes of Health say neoliberalism is not dead. And there is also a very interesting story in the Jacobin, which says the rumors are false. Neoliberalism is alive and well.

Well, this is not the first time that the death of neoliberalism has been announced. I remember back at the end of the 1980s, the IMF and World Bank structural adjustment programs were inflicted upon third world country after third world country, each followed in short order by IMF riots against critical food and fuel subsidies being reversed, social spending being cut, joblessness rising, thanks to the recessions induced by these very programs.

And a World Bank report at the end of this period, essentially admitted that the neoliberal recipe was certainly not working in restoring productive dynamism to any economy upon which it had been inflicted. I also remember the death of neoliberalism being announced after the 1997-98 East Asian financial crisis, when the so-called “Committee to Save the World”, as Time Magazine called it, a committee allegedly consisting of Alan Greenspan, Larry Summers, and Rahm Emanuel, who were allegedly saving the world economy from a neoliberalism induced meltdown.

After the 2008 financial crisis, practically everyone was talking about the return of Keynes, the end of neoliberalism, the return of the state, while Alan Greenspan was admitting before a congressional committee that he had been partially wrong about his free market approach to banking, that the crisis had left him in a state of shocked disbelief. He said, I have found a flaw. I don’t know how significant or permanent it is, but I have been very distressed by this fact. And he said further, I made a mistake in presuming that the self interests of organizations, specifically banks and others, were such that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders and their equity in the funds.

However, even after this massive sort of watershed event, the real story that emerged from it was, as the title of one book about the subject had it, the strange non-death of neoliberalism. And today we have Bidenomics being hailed as the final slayer of the dragon of neoliberalism. Clinton’s Labor Secretary Robert Wright, for instance, thinks that Biden is about to alter the structure of the U.S. economy in ways that help the vast majority and that voters will give Biden another term and reward Democrats with both houses of Congress because it will have transformed the economy in favor of the 90 percent and of workers and unions.

And yet other columnists are praising the same actions of the Biden administration and the same legislative actions as the best business opportunity ever. So even after all these crises, neoliberalism seems to be, if not alive and kicking, at least leading a zombie existence and refuses to die. So today we want to talk about neoliberalism, what it is, where it came from, and why it seems not to die. And what will happen if it dies, and other such questions. So Michael, I’m sure you want to get in here and say something. Please go ahead.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, you’ve just made the point that neoliberalism wants to make itself invisible. It’s like the devil. If there a devil, the devil wants to say he doesn’t exist. Neoliberalism says inequality doesn’t exist, exploitation doesn’t exist, and everything is quite fair.

And what it really wants to make invisible or actually disappear in reality is the government. Neoliberalism advocates an economy without government regulation, with no social protection against fraud or exploitation or predatory impoverishment, no usury laws. They’re against consumer protection. They’re against the ability of debtors to use bankruptcy, which is why Biden made sure that students could not wipe out their student loans through bankruptcy, to free themselves from debt.

So neoliberalism, basically, it’s a dynamic of economic polarization. Neoliberalism is a way in which they can justify why the economy is getting more and more unequal, as if this is a perfectly natural thing, a survival of the fittest, and is really a road to efficiency. And in that sense, neoliberalism is a point—this requires a point of view. It’s an ideology. You could almost say it’s the new religion because it’s a new moral value.

Instead of religion saying we’re for mutual aid and we want to uplift the population as a whole, neoliberalism is saying greed is good, Ayn Rand is good, we want to be free from government, free from government regulation, so the rich can do whatever they want to get rich. And if they do get rich, it’s because they’re productive, not because there’s any exploitation. So neoliberalism is really a cloak of invisibility for all of the problems that we’re seeing today.

RADHIKA DESAI: Well, I mean, this is really interesting, isn’t it? Because there’s just so much smoke and mirrors about it, and there’s even smoke and mirrors about the whole question of invisibility, etc. So on the one hand, of course, we know that in the neoliberal era, markets are imposed on, essentially, the ordinary people, on workers, therefore are forced to compete with one another, especially with the attack on unions and so on and so forth.

But meanwhile, as we have seen, after four decades of neoliberalism, it has often entailed socialism for the rich and competition and neoliberalism for the poor, so the rich get bailed out. So in that sense, I think it’s really worth unpacking this a little bit more. Because on the one hand, you’re right, of course, that they kind of, you know, the other part of smoke and mirrors is that neoliberalism claims that it’s about having no government intervention whatsoever. But in reality, the neoliberal period has seen an enormous amount of government intervention.

If you look at practically any country, including the United States, the onset of the neoliberal era has seen only a slight reduction in the role of the state in the economy, and in many cases, hardly anything, any at all. So in that sense, it hasn’t been about markets. Secondly, you know, on the one hand, they want to say, oh, well, you know, we are doing nothing, the state is doing nothing, this is just the outcome of the market.

On the other hand, neoliberalism has also announced itself. So for example, you know, Mrs. Thatcher is very famous for having said, I think sometime in the 70s, before she became a prime minister, she was very aware, she said the other side have an ideology, we need to have one too. So in that sense, neoliberalism was very much a sort of a counter to the sort of center left ideology, whether you call it Keynesianism or welfarism or what have you. So it was very conscious of being an alternative point of view, which was coming to the fore.

But I think, really, to me, one of the key issues about neoliberalism is that it advertises itself as being all about free markets and competition. But in reality, when you look at it, it’s historically been about preserving the power of big monopoly capital. That’s what it’s been about above all else.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, the key trick word there is market, and especially free market. And what neoliberalism claims is a market or a free market is exactly the opposite of everything that the classical economists, Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, even Marx, talked about what a free market is. Any market is shaped by the social institutions. A market is shaped by the tax laws, by the criminal laws, by all sorts of government regulations. There’s no such thing as a market without government. And if you do get rid of a government shaping the market, then what you have is the wealthy people shaping the market.

Well, what did Adam Smith mean by a free market in the whole 19th century? It was a market free from the legacy of feudalism. We’ve talked about this before. A market without a landlord class that was taking money in their sleep to make money without working. A market free of monopolies. That’s what Adam Smith criticized. He wanted to get rid of landlords and monopolies. And that’s what the entire 19th century was about in describing value and price theory.

Classical economics of free markets looked at any market in terms of value and price theory. Value was the socially necessary cost of production. Value was the cost of producing something. But market prices could be way above this cost, such as, and that was economic rent. Rent was the excess of price over and above the actual value. For instance, if you’re charging someone for the use of land for housing, the land doesn’t have a cost. That’s just there. There’s a legal privilege to privatize and appropriate the land and add the costs. The same thing for monopolies. A monopoly is just the legal right to charge whatever you want and have prices far in excess of the cost of production. So that was a free market.

What neoliberalism has done is erased the whole history of economic language and economic terminology and replaced it with saying a free market is a market free for the rent seekers, a market free for landlords to charge whatever they want for rent without any regulation, free for monopolists to be able to charge whatever the market would bear. And if people are willing to pay $10,000 a year, $20,000 for health care, that’s what the market would bear, your money or your life. That basically is the neoliberal slogan.

And in order to do this concept of their kind of a market, a rentier market, they have to erase the whole history of economic thought and even economic history to say, what happens when there’s a market like this? Well, you look at the Roman Empire and when it collapsed, that’s what happened when you had an oligarchy like this. So neoliberalism in that sense, it’s a market, but it’s an oligarchic market, not a democratic market.

RADHIKA DESAI: And you know, you make a very good point, Michael. So I just want to say two things. First of all, you make a very good point. What are prices? Prices are really based on the value of things, which is based on the cost of production of that thing. But in reality, of course, market prices can be, as you put it, way above that. But I would say something else. I would say that in addition to that, market prices for the vast majority of producers are often below their cost. That is to say, they suffer. So workers get market prices for their labor below their cost. Peasants and small producers and mom and pop store owners and business owners get prices that are often way below their production costs and so on. So really, as you rightly say, it’s an oligarchic, it encourages an oligarchic form of production. But I also, so that’s my first point.

But I wanted to take the conversation further also on another point you made. And that is that, you know, you said that neoliberalism is really about erasing the entire tradition of solid economic discourse that was carried on up until the late 19th century. So what happened in the late 19th century? This is very important.

In the late 19th century, on the one hand, Marx and Engels brought the tradition of classical political economy of which Adam Smith or Ricardo were such a big part. They brought it to its culmination by resolving so many of its unresolved problems. What exactly was value? What was surplus value? Where did it come from? How was it that the same amount of capital deployed in different proportions between capital and labor, you know, was it supposed to yield equal rates of profit? Et cetera. All of these were really interesting questions.

Marx and Engels, with their ability to think through all these questions in a dialectical manner, they resolved these problems. And the result was a huge indictment of capitalism. And in fact, even under Ricardo, sorry, please go ahead, Michael, I’ll continue.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Before you go on to that, your point about labor at less than its cost of production, that’s very important because if labor is paid less than its cost of living, it’s forced into debt. And that’s the important thing. Not only is what the rentier class, the landlords and monopolists charge over the cost of production to get a free lunch, but if labor is less than the cost of production, it’s driven into debt, and it’s driven into debt to the creditor class, and this debt becomes a wedge that polarizes the economy. So the market there polarizes.

RADHIKA DESAI: Absolutely. And I would say that even more, I mean, labor, yes, of course, if there is anybody who is going to give them any credit in the first place, because that’s not always been the case. But I would also say that this has historically applied to peasants and small producers of every variety. And that’s why peasants have this constant cycle of debt that they are in, because their products never bring in the kind of return that is necessary.

But to return to the point about what happened in the late 19th century. So, you know, if Marx and Engels brought neoclassical economics to a culmination, Ricardo, even before Marx and Engels, Ricardo’s insistence that all value originated in labor was itself the basis of the various currents of Ricardian socialism. So this type of thinking, economic thinking, which was very good and solid, was already giving rise to anti-capitalist currents, even before Marx. Once Marx comes around, things are going downhill very rapidly. And that’s when you get a completely different way of thinking, making its appearance in the form of neoclassical economics.

And it’s important to remember that neoclassical economics, which emerged in the 1870s, of course, there were some sort of socialistic elements of neoclassical economics. We’ll leave those aside. But on the whole, it was a complete commitment to free market thinking, particularly in its Austrian version. And that free market economics has been developed, and it survived throughout the Keynesian period. And almost 100 years after it was first born, it finally achieved the influence that it did with the election of governments like Thatcher and Reagan and so on, and has been afflicting our world for the last 40 years.

So neoliberalism, it’s very important to remember, is essentially this extreme free market version of neoclassical economics. And it essentially erases all these questions. For example, neoclassical economics does not recognize anything like value. It does not talk about production, but about markets and exchange. It doesn’t talk about values, but it talks about prices. It does not think of capitalism as a historically specific way of organizing society. It thinks that it’s been around since Lucy, it’s been around since the earliest days of humankind. So in all of these ways, neoclassical economics represents a deterioration in economic thinking.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, that means that neoliberalism really should be called anti-liberalism. Because if liberalism was the classical idea of free markets, free of rent and interest and monopoly rent, then the justification of all these is that the market should include rent as being productive. Then this is the opposite.

And so neoliberalism, it’s an anti-social philosophy. That’s what the Austrians were. They said, we have a definition of markets that doesn’t have society at all. As you mentioned, Margaret Thatcher said, there’s no such thing as society. So you have a neoliberal view of society as well as markets without government, without anything that is subsidized, without any social feeling. It’s all individualism. As if you can make the whole society with individualism, there is no public infrastructure because any infrastructure is privatized. There is no public credit and money creation because all money creation, instead of being a public utility, it’s all privatized. And that lets the bankers create the money. The bankers receive the interest on loans of this money. The bankers lend to the landlord class to buy real estate and oil wells and mines and extract economic rent.

So the Austrian economics is really a rationale of fighting back, saying we’re against any reform that is going to make the government the recipient of natural resource rent and land rent and income. It should all go to the wealthy class. That was sort of the last attempt to sort of fight against the whole of free market liberalism that was occurring.

And it was not only Austria, it was in the United States by John Bates Clark saying there is no such thing as unearned income. Everybody earns whatever they want. The landlord earns the rent and the crook earns what he can take.

RADHIKA DESAI: Well, this is exactly, you know, and you know, this is another way in which neoclassical economics, which is the basis of neoliberalism, is different from the tradition of classical political economy, because you see, there was a sense in which in classical political economy, whether they although they didn’t use the term or Karl Polanyi used the term, apparently he got it from from (unclear), the term I’m talking about is fictitious commodities, but they knew that land. labor and money were not commodities, although they were treated in capitalism as if they were commodities. And this led to a whole range of difficulties and problems that Polanyi talked about in great detail.

What’s really interesting, and many people think that what Polanyi said has nothing to do with Marx or with the traditional classical political economy, but it does for the very simple reason that the awareness that land, labor and money were not commodities was reflected in classical political economy by the simple point that all the entire tradition of classical political economy from Smith to Ricardo to Marx, they are all concerned about finding the special laws through which the rent of land, the wages of labor and the interest of money are set. They knew that they are not commodities, so their prices are not set like all the other commodities. There are special laws that determine the wages of labor, the rent of land and the interest of money. So in that sense, they were very aware of this. So this is a very, very different thing.

And so in classical political economy, as you say, all incomes are earned incomes because there is really no question. They don’t really understand the difference between earned income and unearned income. This is the key point. And of course, they even sort of laugh at Polanyi for even using a term like classical political economy. But fundamentally, I also want to say that neoliberal economics, neoclassical free market economics is essentially bad faith economics because it emerges in the 1870s and develops over the next many decades, precisely during the decades when capitalism in its homelands was becoming monopoly capitalism. Precisely at that time, they are celebrating free markets and competition, precisely that which is being erased, in fact.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, that’s what de-industrialized the United States, not recognizing the difference between earned and unearned income. You have exactly what’s happened really since the 1980s, since Ronald Reagan here and Thatcher’s there. So you could say that this view of the world leads to not curing the problems, not freeing society from the rentier and creditor interests, but it ends up by you de-industrialize.

The neoliberals agree with Marx that the profits are all made out of employing labor and charging more for what labor produces than what it costs to employ it. But instead of what Marx said, well, let’s raise the price of labor so that labor gets to buy and receive what it produces, the neoliberals say we have to lower the price of labor. It’s an anti-labor strategy.

And this is why under the Clinton administration in the 1990s, America said, how do we lower the price of American labor to increase profits here? Well, we’ll shift labor to China, to Asia, to where labor has paid lower wages and therefore we’ll put American labor in competition with Asian labor and we’ve de-industrialized. All that was the result of following the neoliberal game plan of how to get rich and meaning how to get rich if you’re one of the 1%, not the 99%.

RADHIKA DESAI: No, exactly. And there’s another way in which, so the first point like I’m saying is that just when capitalism is shifting to becoming monopoly capitalism, that’s when they suddenly start talking about competition because the fact is the competition and is the only way in which capitalism can be justified because the idea is that competition imposes upon the capitalists themselves a certain type of discipline that forces them to be more productive. So, and therefore it develops the forces of production, however, brutally and chaotically it may do so, at least it does that.

But once capitalism arrives at the monopoly phase, Marx was very clear at this point, it was ripe for transition to socialism. So think about it. Neoliberalism emerges as an ideology to defend capitalism at that point in historical time when the bell was already tolling for it. In that sense, neoliberalism has been fighting a rear guard battle for all these decades.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, it’s an attack on industrial capitalism. A neoliberalism isn’t the result of industrial capitalism. Industrial capitalism wanted to lower the price of labor by having the government provide most of the living costs of labor. The government would provide healthcare, not the workers that corporations would have to pay high enough salaries to afford healthcare, education, and basic needs. So Marx had believed that neoliberalism would fade away because neoliberalism was a defense of the landlord interests and the feudal interests.

You talked about monopoly capitalism. There were always monopolies in the sense of natural monopolies, such as transportation, communications, and neoliberalism wants to privatize these monopolies to take them out of state hands where the government would provide natural monopoly services, transportation, water supply, healthcare, at cost or at a subsidized price. By monopolizing them, you create an enormous source of revenue. Basically it’s rent revenue, and most neoliberal wealth is not made by industrial production. Neoliberal wealth is made by taking assets from the public domain, especially monopolies, especially the transportation system, especially the electrical system, especially the communication system. They privatize healthcare. They privatize education. All of this is taken away from the government.

So you had two competing philosophies leading up to the years just before World War I. You have industrial capitalism evolving into socialism saying we want to have the government provide basic needs of labor so that we don’t have to pay the costs and we can compete with countries that privatize all these services. And then you had the Austrian-American, the privatizers wanting to fight back and saying we want to get rid of government and prevent them from doing this. We want the economy to be free for the privatizers to grab Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan style.

RADHIKA DESAI: But if I may, Michael, you’re absolutely right, of course, that there are natural monopolies, but I think that there are two different types of monopolies and I’m talking about them both, of course, but I think it’s important to distinguish between the two.

The first is, of course, the natural monopolies. Land is a natural monopoly. Moneymaking is a natural monopoly, et cetera. That is to say the creation of money is a natural monopoly of the state and so on. I mean, there are many, as you say, transportation, blah, blah, and so on. All of these things are true.

What Marx, however, is talking about when he talks about the capitalism arriving at the monopoly phase is that the unfolding of the process of competition itself will lead, the natural result of it is the creation of monopolies because after the process of competition has eliminated all the inefficient producers, there is only one or a handful left standing and that creates a context in which essentially society moves from competitive capitalism, even in the non-natural monopoly sectors, to monopoly capitalism where a small number of really big producers tend to monopolize everything.

Marx felt that once this stage was reached and there was nothing necessarily wrong with it, this is what capitalism was doing and it was leading to more efficient production, but it was more efficient production based on a massive socialization of labor involving the cooperation of thousands and hundreds of thousands of people in a single industrial enterprise.

And Marx felt that once this stage had been reached, everybody would be able to see that the myth of the heroic entrepreneur who is owed vast profits, et cetera, is a myth and the myth would be exposed and therefore people would be ready to take things into public hands. People would say, this is our labor, this is social labor and it should be socialized and it should be publicly owned. This is what neoliberalism has made a tremendous contribution to preventing so far.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, there are two kinds of monopolies. Now, what you describe, Marx is describing monopolization under industrial capitalism, but some monopolies are natural monopolies. That’s what governments have kept in the public domain like the postal service and other things.

And within industrial capitalism, already in the 19th century, the American laws and presidents said, banks are the mother of trusts and the antitrust laws in the United States that began to be passed in the 1890s realized that the bankers were organizing industry into trust, that this monopolization was not simply the workings of the marketplace that Marx described, but it was actually done in a predatory way by the banks buying up all of the steel companies and making the steel trust, buying up credit to merge all of the copper companies and making a copper trust to make sure that there was not competition. So that while neoliberalism promises to be a doctrine of free competition to everybody fighting to lower the price, it actually is to prevent competition by monopolizing the entire economy so that you can charge high monopoly rents.

As you’re seeing, this is what the legal cases today in the United States, the one good thing that Biden has done, which he’s very embarrassed at having done and doesn’t talk about it is the antitrust laws. You’ve had the antitrust ruling against Google. You’ve had a whole set of antitrust rulings that are being revived today to try to save the economy from being monopolized.

And this is something that Marx did not anticipate, the degree to which industrial capitalism would lose the fight against finance capitalism and essentially not defend its interest, but would be co-opted and somehow evolve into this basically anti-capitalist financialization and neoliberalism that is so economically self-destructive that there’s very little way that you can look at, this is a dynamic of the laws of motion because it’s the law of stopping motion, a law of degrowth, not growth.

RADHIKA DESAI: No, I must say on this point, I would slightly disagree with you, Michael, because the thing is, it’s important to remember that antitrust is actually one of the keystones of neoliberalism.

Let me explain what I mean. So, first of all, let me agree with you, what you were saying earlier, that in the United States, banks like J.P. Morgan played a leading role in essentially the cartelization, the monopolization, the trustification of the economy in the late 19th and early 20th centuries. And of course, Hilferding across the water was talking about similar trends in Germany where banks were playing a central role in aiding the monopolization of capital. But while banks aided it, this was a natural tendency of capitalism.

What Marx pointed out is that at this point, once you arrived at the monopoly phase, it was time to shift to socialism. Indeed, many people laugh at Hilferding because Hilferding said something like, you only have to nationalize six large Berlin banks in order to essentially take a bulk of the German economy into public ownership. But he was right because these banks, through their activity in aiding monopoly, had indeed created that sort of economy. He wasn’t talking about the banks of today, which have very little to do with production. At that time, particularly in Germany, they were very different types of banks.

So, banks were certainly aiding the process of monopolization, but what Lenin called monopoly capital, what Hilferding called finance capital, and what Buharin called the nationalization of capital were all referring to the same thing, that all the major capitalist societies were now dominated by big monopoly corporations. Marx thought that this was the time for socialism.

Antitrust law, therefore, arrives at this point to help the neoliberal defenders of capitalism to try to maintain the appearance of a certain minimum level of competition while actually continuing to have the monopoly structure of the capitalist economy. If it’s not monopoly, then it’s oligopoly, and the competition is largely in name. And it is really, at this point, you go from justifying capitalism in terms of competition to justifying capitalism in terms of consumer welfare.

Because remember now, the fate of capitalism is not being decided in the market as it once was in the competitive phase, but in the courtrooms of antitrust law. So, the whole purpose of antitrust law is to try to mask the fact that capitalism is now past its sell-by date and we have to do something much more radical. And this has been true now for about a century at least.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Okay, you’re talking about structural monopoly of how the economy is structured as opposed to just the competition within a given industry. So, we’re talking about monopoly. I agree with what you said. We’re just talking about two different kinds of monopoly. The structural monopoly of how wealth is made and then the specific industrial monopolies in particular industries.

RADHIKA DESAI: And you know, Michael, though, at the same time, what you were saying earlier, and I think this is absolutely critically important, is very true. Today, what we are seeing is that big monopoly corporate capital is preying upon, of course, first of all, in the days of more robust development of capitalism, even as it was entering in the monopoly phase, what we witnessed was that often the natural monopolistic activities, whether it was transportation or utilities or what have you, were actually often performed by the state. So, you had a fair amount of state ownership, whether it was at the municipal level or the state level or the federal level, you had a fair amount of state ownership.

Now, what we are seeing is the attempt by capital on the one hand to privatize those natural monopolies that were hitherto created and maintained by the state, for the purpose of private profit. And then also, of course, preying upon every other monopoly on which they could try and get their hands, whether it is health services or water provisional utilities or transportation, education, you name it, the private capital has got its fingers in every one of these spies.

And its purpose is not productive expansion, but rather the purpose today is to skim off the incomes, the ever shrinking share of incomes that are actually made by producing something. And these are largely made by workers, by smaller enterprises, and so on and so forth. And this is what is done through the entire structure of indebting the economy, whether you are indebting households or you’re indebting businesses or you’re indebting governments. And this is the way in which today’s financial monopoly capitalism is skimming off income.

But there is one other thing that I also want to introduce in here, which is that-

MICHAEL HUDSON: You should make one point at a time, not two points.

RADHIKA DESAI: Sorry, I will wait, I will wait, you go ahead.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Okay, what you said is what I said earlier in our discussion. I said, most wealth under neoliberalism is made by privatizing the public domain. And the fight between socialism and neoliberalism is who is going to provide for natural monopolies and basic needs? Who will provide healthcare, education, communications, transportation? Are these going to be public services provided at a low cost for everybody? Or will it be essentially privatized and monopolized, as you say, so that these natural monopolies are going to be able to become vehicles to squeeze out economic rent.

And economic rent is really the key objective of neoliberalism. Not so much profits, but monopoly rent. So neoliberalism denies that there’s any distinction between monopoly rent and profit. As opposed to classical economics that made a very clear distinction. There are rent recipients and profit recipients. And they’re antithetical, not together.

RADHIKA DESAI: And the reason why it’s so important to make this distinction between rent as unearned income, versus wages and profits as having at least some kind of earned element in it, is the simple fact that this, it draws attention to where production is involved. But of course, neoclassical economics is habituated to not focusing on production at all.

But yeah, okay, so I entirely agree with you. And I just wanted to say that in order to understand why we are in this position today, where you say the purpose of all capital today, especially in countries like the United States, seems to be to essentially prey upon and earn rents from these monopoly activities and so on. How did we come here?

Well, I just want to throw in one further thought, which is that, what I was saying earlier, that Marx was expecting that once capitalism arrived at this monopoly phase, that people would realize that it was important to socialize it, et cetera. Now, of course, neoliberalism came along and neoclassical economics came along and started producing these inherently false, and I would say that they were bad faith defenses of capitalism.

But nevertheless, all their efforts could not prevent the cataclysmic crisis. So what Arnold Mayer called the 30 years crisis of 1914 to 1945, from erupting, which involved inter-imperialist wars, which involved Great Depression, and finally, nuclear weapons, the Holocaust, and what have you. All of these things happen, and by the end of this period, I would say that most people were convinced that capitalism, really, that the world was going to move away from capitalism, that capitalism had shown the destruction that it would cause, the misery that it could cause, and that the world was not going to stand for it. People like Keynes or Polanyi expected that the world would move radically leftwards.

But then you got the golden age of capitalism, and most people attributed that golden age of capitalism to capitalism itself, sorry, the golden age of world growth, I should say, they attributed it to capitalism. They said, you know, people like Keynes or Polanyi were wrong, and others who thought that, you know, the capitalism would end in the post-Second World War period, they were wrong. Capitalism had regained its mojo and everything was fine.

But in reality, what we can, what becomes very clear after 40 years of neoliberalism, is that the real source of growth in this period, after three decades after the Second World War, lay in the fact that monopoly capitalism was heavily regulated, was ringed around with the institutions or with socialistic institutions and practices, whether it is the practice of macroeconomic management for full employment, the creation of welfare states, the expansion, massive expansion of domestic demand, etc., and all of these things, these socialistic measures, these are what account for the dynamism of capitalism.

Why can we see that? For the simple reason that after this model got into crisis, not because of the socialistic measures, but because the underlying system remained capitalist. After the crisis of the 70s, when the governments of these countries took the turn to neoliberalism and rolled back many of these socialistic measures, you did not get a revival of capitalism, but the transformation, the morphing of capitalism into the system that you were describing, Michael, as preying upon, you know, public enterprises, privatizing them, and essentially using the state as a (unclear) from which to make unearned profits.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, there’s also another factor that we haven’t discussed yet that gave the appearance of capitalism having a golden age after 1945, and that is that every country emerged from World War II almost free of debt, because the Depression had basically wiped out debt, and during the war, consumers were not going into debt because there was nothing they could buy. Corporations weren’t going into debt, and after the war, there were no reparations on the defeated parties as after World War I, so you had every economy beginning with what in Germany was called the economic miracle, a debt-free society.

Now, there were many business cycles after 1945, but each cycle started from a higher and higher debt level, and this rising debt increased the power of creditors and the bringing to power of Thatcher and Reagan and neoliberalism in the 1980s was largely a result of all of this growth in creditor power that resulted from the growth of debt, meaning of savings in the hands of the creditor class that found its counterpart on the other side of the balance sheet in debt by labor, by corporations, and by government, so the governments essentially were prone to a debt squeeze.

You had, since the 1980s, the International Monetary Fund telling countries, well, you have to pay your foreign creditors, and the way you’re going to pay your foreign dollar holders, basically, you’re going to have to sell off your infrastructure to monopolize it. It was debt that forced the privatization of monopolies throughout the global south, largely through the IMF and the World Bank, so you had a neoliberalism that was not only debt-based, but also, as we’ve discussed in our earlier broadcasts, that this is a U.S.-centered phenomenon because after World War II, the creditor-oriented system was really based on the U.S. dollar and U.S. government debt, which essentially was debt run up by balance of payment deficits to pay for America’s military control, and that is what neoliberalism leaves out.

Neoliberalism is wrapped in the iron military fist of 800 American military bases to make sure that there is no alternative. If you’re going to have no alternative, you need to enforce neoliberalism militarily, and that globalizes neoliberalism in the way that we’ve been talking about.

RADHIKA DESAI: I agree with what you say, but I would confine all of that to the neoliberal period because why does debt rise so exponentially in the neoliberal period? It rises exponentially in the neoliberal period because, first of all, the income of workers is being squeezed because there’s an attack on unions and, of course, there is a massive outsourcing and so on and so forth, so you get a squeeze on workers’ incomes and if workers need anything, then in that case they have to be indebted.

Secondly, although of course there are a lot of cutbacks of government spending as far as social spending is concerned, on a whole lot of other outlays, government spending does not decrease. Government spending does not decrease in terms of helping industry, subsidizing industry. Government spending does not decrease in terms of military activities. In fact, it increases on all these fronts massively, so government expenditures do not decrease.

Meanwhile, every government, especially every Republican government in the United States, tries to outdo the previous one in giving tax cuts to the rich, so the tax structure becomes increasingly regressive and therefore, of course, there is a debt crisis of governments and, of course, households, that is to say, yeah, I mean, and businesses are also increasingly indebted because as businesses are taken over by bigger businesses, the bigger businesses or financial interests that take over businesses are only interested in borrowing as much as they can on the basis of the collateral that that business provides, so they burden every business with as much debt that it can possibly take in order to essentially appropriate dividends and profits for themselves.

So in all of these ways, neoliberalism has led to a massive increase in debt and this is itself, to me, a result of the fact that freeing capital, freeing monopoly capital from the burdens of state regulation and social obligation, has not restored to capitalism any kind of productive mojo. It has only set capital, monopoly capital, free to prey upon the earned incomes of the rest of the world, so a tiny elite has as a consequence been getting ever richer at the expense of the vast majority of working people in the world.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, I think the protector of monopoly capital was basically the financial interests and there was an exponential growth of debt beginning already in 1945. There was a build-up of pressure of increasing wealth and concentration of financial wealth that enabled the financial class to really take the lead in protecting monopolies and playing a catalystic and ultimately controlling role in the monopolization. So you have to look at this interaction between the financial sector and the rest.

RADHIKA DESAI: Well, I’ll say two things. Number one, I would say that first of all, if you look at, if you chart the amount of debt in the world, yes, sure it was increasing in the post-second world war period, but there is absolutely no doubt that it goes, I mean, it may be increasing like so, but then it spikes up in the neoliberal period in very noticeable ways.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Yes, because it was created.

RADHIKA DESAI: Yeah, exactly. And on the matter of the United States dollar and the dollar system, the fact of the matter is that again, the amount of debt the United States incurred as a result of the operation of the dollar system compared to what we have today in terms of the sheer amount of debt, not just the US debt to the world, which is a small part of it, but just the explosion of debt of all sorts. Again, it is out of proportion and this explosion of debt and the financial markets upon which it rests and the speculation to which it has given rise to, these are the things, not just the US’s current account deficit that accounts for the indebtedness of the world. The US’s current account deficit, big though it is, is a small portion of the largest structure of indebtedness.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Okay, you made an important distinction that is often left out of account. You’re absolutely right. When I talked about compound interest increasing exponentially, that’s interest on debt that is already in place. But what you’ve just mentioned is the very important fact that most debt isn’t simply the accumulation of interest on past credit, it’s actually the creation of new debt by banks simply creating bank money. And that’s exactly what’s happened. That was the explosion, the creation of bank money, which in a way you could call it the privatization of the monopoly of credit creation. And the credit creation was created, as you just pointed out, out of all proportion to the productive use of credit or to the means of production. It wasn’t created to create new means of production, but to buy existing means of production to take them over and monopolize them, downsize them and financialize them.

RADHIKA DESAI: No, exactly. And you know, Michael, this has been such an absorbing discussion, but I also noticed that we have only been through a fraction of the points that we wanted to go through. But let me just start bringing this hour to a close. We may do another session on the same subject, but let me start bringing this hour to a close by mentioning just one important thing that I think we should put out there, whether or not we do another hour on this.

And that is that precisely because neoliberalism was never an accurate theory of how the economy works or even how the capitalist economy works, precisely because neoliberalism, although, you know, was incapable of delivering the kind of prosperity that it was promising. As a result of that, it has been shifting shape about once every decade. So once every of each one of the four decades that we have seen, we have seen a slightly different type of neoliberalism. And as a consequence, the current debate, the current announcements of the demise of neoliberalism are also not going to lead to… are also, you know, the reports of the death of neoliberalism are greatly exaggerated.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, you’re right. Neoliberalism in practice doesn’t work. And yet, if it doesn’t work, and it’s junk economics, what it has done to conceal the fact that it doesn’t work is to redesign the whole picture of the economy that’s depicted in the national income accounts and the GDP accounts. And it actually depicts this unproductive, predatory, rentier overhead as if it’s a product, a product, as if rents are a product. That’s it.

RADHIKA DESAI: No, absolutely. So on the one hand, it sort of tries to create the illusion of growth. You know, right now, everybody’s saying that the United States is growing. But how much of that growth is purely financial growth? So that’s absolutely right. And as I say, we must talk about this as well.

But I just wanted to finish the point. So in the 1980s, you got classic neoliberalism, you know, markets good, states bad. And this is what’s going to lead to prosperity. By the end of the 80s, this was no longer so. Then in the 1990s, you got a different neoliberalism. This was the neoliberalism of globalization. It was enforced not by right wing, new right governments like Reagan and Thatcher, but by new labor and sort of, you know, Clintonite, you know, third way governments like Clinton and Blair and so on and so forth.

And what did they say? They did not deny that neoliberalism was very punishing for ordinary people. And they said to their mostly working class support base, they said, we would love to raise your wages, we would love to increase welfare, we would love to have, you know, better environmental protection. But you know what, our hands are tied, our hands are tied by globalization. Globalization is this unstoppable juggernaut, that’s not going not going to, you know, we’re going to have to bow to it. By the 2000s, you’ve got jobs.

Two more, three more points. So by George Bush, Jr, you got the US as an empire. And by this time, Europe was suffering from euro-sclerosis, and Japan was not doing well. So the United States economy, especially with the housing and credit bubbles was made to look, you know, with great difficulty, of course, but made to look like it was somehow a very dynamic economy. After 2008, you got the massive period of austerity. That was the neoliberalism of the 2010s. And now we are going to see a new version of neoliberalism.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, you’re talking about the conflict between illusion and reality. And in the United States, all of the polls show that consumers, workers, consumers are the neoliberal word for workers, say that they’re much worse off.

And President Biden keeps saying, how can you be worse off? Read Paul Krugman in the New York Times, and he said GDP is up. Well, GDP is up, but all the GDP is occurring to the monopoly class, finance, insurance, and real estate, not to the workers. So when they talked about a boom with GDP up, that’s again for the neoliberalized rentier economy.

So the way to make a transition, I guess, from what we’re talking about now to our future broadcasts, is just ask yourself, would China have been better off if it would have abandoned its socialism and adopted the U.S. neoliberal model back in 1990 with Clinton? Should China have just said, well, Russia invited the neoliberals in to just close down all of our industry and give everything in the public sector to the ruling class and the gangs for free? Would China have been better off if it would have followed the Russian Boris Yeltsin’s plan in the 1990s and the Clinton plan in the United States and the Obama plan? Or would it have been better off being socialism? Once you ask that question, you begin to say, what is neoliberalism leaving out of account?

RADHIKA DESAI: Well, exactly. And so, you know, I mean, bang on, you know, I don’t think that the rest of the world is going to do and, you know, the rest of the world is going to benefit by imitating what the U.S. is doing.

But in the U.S. itself, you know, this idea that somehow Bidenomics is going to, you know, is now talking about industrial policy and it is going to essentially constitute the rejection of neoliberalism. This is all complete nonsense.

You’d only believe it if you thought neoliberalism was about free markets. Neoliberalism has never been about free markets. It has always been about hiding the fact that capitalism is now in its senile monopoly phase. Instead, you keep talking about competition as though it’s going to revive it. But in any case, it has always been about preserving the power of an ever-shrinking monopoly, financialized monopoly, capitalist elite.

And in this form, Bidenomics, with its massive subsidies to corporations, etc., is just another version of that. In my book, Capitalism, Coronavirus and More, I call what we are now about to see pseudo-civic neoliberalism. That is to say, our governments will tell us the people must have X, Y, Z goods which are free or very cheap. And they will subsidize massively the production of these things, whether it is vaccines or various forms of green technology or transportation, what have you.

And the governments will essentially give vast subsidies to private corporations to produce these things, which they will sell at high cost to government. And government will then allegedly make it available to us, either for cheap or for free, at least in name. But the fact of the matter is, we are going to pay for it through our taxes. And we are also going to pay for it because the goods and services we get will be so shoddy that they will probably not be worth having. So this is the kind of pseudo-civic neoliberalism that we are about to witness. What is being called Bidenomics is not at all the advent of a new post neoliberal age, but merely the fifth form that neoliberalism will take in its fifth decade.

MICHAEL HUDSON: So neoliberalism is the new Cold War turning into a hot war, basically. It’s a globalized Cold War.

RADHIKA DESAI: I guess, Michael, you might want to elaborate very briefly on it.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, in order to maintain the system, you can’t have a rivalry to neoliberalism. There must be no alternative in the United States. Why is it fighting against China? China is an alternative. Russia is an alternative. If the world sees that the US and NATO, Europe are shrinking, and Eurasia is going way ahead, then there obviously is an alternative, and people are going to ask, what makes the Eurasian multipolar development so different from the world that the United States is trying to create, a neoliberal, financialized, privatized world ruling by force and by client military oligarchies?

RADHIKA DESAI: You’re so right. In a certain sense, this new Cold War is the Cold War. I think it’s like the old Cold War. It’s the Cold War between, on the one hand, those countries that refuse to accept that capitalism is past its sell-by date, and on the other hand, countries that know this and are willing to experiment with all sorts of interesting ways of creating economies that are actually going to work for people. I think that’s the divide we are increasingly going to see.

So that really means, you know, perhaps another program which we must do is, really, we should talk about the international manifestations of neoliberalism over the last four decades, and how they have changed, and how they have brought us to this point of this new Cold War.

But for now, I guess we will say goodbye, and looking forward to seeing you, perhaps not in two weeks, but certainly in early January. So look forward to that, and thank you very much. Bye-bye.

Photo by Michael Held on Unsplash

The post Is It Over Yet? first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Working toward snatching humanist hope from the jaws of the unfolding genocide in Gaza. In conversation with Owen Jones

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 14/12/2023 - 8:29am in

Owen Jones kindly invited me back to his show to discuss, what else, Gaza. We talk about the peculiarity of this genocide (i.e., that its perpetrators do not even care to hide their intent), the forgotten readiness of Western governments to brutalise not only foreign peoples (like the Palestinians) but also their own working classes, the hypocrisy of the West’s invocation of human rights and international law, Joe Biden’s motives and role, the history of settler imperialism (of which Palestine is a tragic repercussion), the brave resistance to Israel’s apartheid by humanist Israeli Jews, and, last but not least, the last source of hope there remains for the end of the slaughter and the granting of human rights to a people that have none – the Palestinians.

Please like, subscribe – and help us take on the pro-war media here: https://www.Patreon.com/owenjones84

The post Working toward snatching humanist hope from the jaws of the unfolding genocide in Gaza. In conversation with Owen Jones appeared first on Yanis Varoufakis.

On the causes and nature of Populism’s Surge – interviewed on BBC Radio 4’s The World This Weekend

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Mon, 11/12/2023 - 10:00am in

Discussing the surge of ultra-rightist populism, where I argued it all started with the West’s response to the 2008 crash – just like after 1929. When $35 trillion was printed on behalf of financiers (between 2009 and 2022), while most people were subjected to some variant of austerity, and given the Left’s failure to defend the majority, the rise of new forms of fascism was inevitable.

The post On the causes and nature of Populism’s Surge – interviewed on BBC Radio 4’s The World This Weekend appeared first on Yanis Varoufakis.

Economists as Hired Guns

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Sun, 26/11/2023 - 12:02am in

Tags 

Interviews

Nov 13 2023 with Steve Keen

Pod version

Published Nov 24

How Finance Capitalism Ruined the World – Dr. Michael Hudson & Dr. Steve Keen

Dr. Michael Hudson is an American economist, Professor of Economics at the University of Missouri–Kansas City and a researcher at the Levy Economics Institute at Bard College, former Wall Street analyst, political consultant, commentator and journalist. Dr. Steve Keen is an Australian economist and author. A post-Keynesian, he criticizes neoclassical economics as inconsistent, unscientific and empirically unsupported. Our conversation examines the false dichotomy of capitalism v. socialism and considers the true dichotomy, which is industrial capitalism v. finance capitalism. Hudson and Keen argue that the transition to finance capitalism, where unearned income is considered economic growth, has truly sown the seeds to ruin the world.

Michael Shilo DeLay

We came down to the idea that the best thing to do might be to get both of your perspectives on why capitalism functions the way that it does, how it functions first of all, as opposed to the way that it’s ideally supposed to function, and then talk about why some of those myths persist about capitalism. And maybe, if we’re really lucky, we will work towards a picture of something better in the future because that’s what I’m personally obsessed with.So… 

Michael Hudson

Obviously, there are different kinds of capitalism, a nd we’re in finance capitalism. And What Steve and I are talking about really is the degeneration and reversal of industrial capitalism —away from its revolution into socialism, and toward finance capitalism, neo-feudalism, and global disaster. It’s supposed to work. It’s supposed to create a global disaster. So 1% of the population owns everything else and can take over the 99%. Isn’t that what’s supposed to work? Yeah, if you’re one of the 1%. So, who’s supposed to work for whom?  

Michael Shilo DeLay

Let’s unpack that history a little bit, from the grand ideal we started.

Steve Keen

Have we started? 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Yeah, we started recording at the very beginning, and then, you know, we’ll probably acts off the beginning until we get rolling.Exactly. But I honestly think we can just launch into it. I’d like to get both of your perspectives on how these events unfolded to the place that we’re at. 

Anastasia Bendebury

So before we get to the events that have unfolded, let’s make sure that… 

Michael Shilo DeLay

We need to do that. 

Anastasia Bendebury

We do need to do in a way.

Michael Shilo DeLay

We have one more tactical thing

Anastasia Bendebury

Alright, that’s a good call. Okay, so I’m going to clap here and then… 

Michael Shilo DeLay

We use this title on the audio. So if each of you in turn, we can maybe start with Michael. If you could say something with a ‘P’ like Karl Popper, perhaps… 

Michael Hudson

Karl Popper.  

Michael Shilo DeLay

Got it. And then Steve.  

Michael Hudson

Peter picked up a pack of pickled peppers.

Anastasia Bendebury

Yeah.  

Michael Shilo DeLay

Nice. Right?  

Anastasia Bendebury

Okay.

Michael Shilo DeLay

I think that’s how.  

Michael Hudson

Get that explosiveness that pumpkins up.

Steve Keen

Yeah, that’s all. How I’ll go for Polanyi.

Anastasia Bendebury

Okay.

Steve Keen

So I’m not Popper.

Anastasia Bendebury

I want us to start with making sure that everyone is on the same page for what we’re talking about. So when we say that capitalism is broken or it’s not working, do both of you have the same vision for what that means? Or do you have slightly different perspectives or totally different perspectives on how it’s going? 

Michael Shilo DeLay

What that word means? It’s such a huge, powerful word in this discussion. We should probably define it as vigorously as possible. 

Michael Hudson

Well, first of all, that’s the wrong question. ‘Working for whom?’ It’s working very good if you’re one of the 1%. It’s working very badly if you’re one of the 99% or if you’re living in a part of the world that the rising sea levels are going to make uncomfortable, or if you’re a renter and not a homeowner, or if you’re a debtor, not a creditor. So it’s working. For whom is the first question? 

Michael Shilo DeLay

What is it? What is capitalism? I know this is a very elementary question, but I think it’s really important that we define that term up front.

Michael Hudson

The word ‘capitalism’ was coined in the early 20th century by the chairman. I’m always plucking out his name right now.

Steve Keen

It’s from Plato. 

Michael Hudson

No, no, no. Who wrote ‘The Bourgeois’? Many of us. I’m blocking it all out. Right. Well, think what most people think of as capitalism is what Marx wrote about, describing industrial capitalism, where the distinguishing feature is wage labor. Industrialists will hire labor to produce a good to sell at a profit. And the idea is for capitalists in one country to undersell those of other countries and continually cut costs so that they can undersell their rivals. Modern finance capitalism is the opposite. Finance Capitalism or ‘Pentagon capitalism’ aims to maximize the cost of production. In ‘Pentagon capitalism,’ you’re paid an automatic 10% or similar proportion of whatever you spend money on. So the objective of ‘Pentagon capitalism’ is instead of making a $20 toilet seat, you make the famous $350 toilet seat because then you get a $35 10% commission. Is that capitalism? The kind of capitalism we have today?

If you want to say is capitalism, what we now have is finance capitalism, and that’s the antithesis of industrial capitalism. Industrial capitalism sought to cut costs, and how do you do it? You do it by having the government play a rising role. The government would make sure that costs are not increased by monopolies because any natural monopoly is going to be taken into the public domain. Communications, health care, education, transportation—all of these were developed by the government and supplied to the private sector at a discount or even freely so that the wage earners who were hired by the employers didn’t have to spend their wages on health care or education. And that enabled American and German wages not to include all of these extra costs because of government.

The ideal of industrial capitalism was revolutionary. It was to get rid of the rent seekers, to get rid of economic rent as unearned income, to get rid of the landlord class by taxing away land rent, to get rid of the monopolists by putting monopolies in the public domain, or at least regulating them. What happened was the rent seekers fought back and gave us modern economics. Modern economics said that government plays no major economic role. The one thing it picked up from industrial capitalism was to say any problem has a solution. The solution to every problem is one of two things: one, lower the wages of labor and its living standards; two, get rid of government and let the private market solve everything.

As long as the market is controlled by the financial interests. The ideal of finance capitalism is to replace economic planning away from the government towards the financial centers and to maximize economic rent. By the end of the 19th century, modern economics saying markets are ideal the way they are. Any attempt to change the natural market is an interference with the market. And the interference they meant was they didn’t want socialism to develop, they didn’t want economic regulation to develop, they didn’t want anti-monopoly regulation to develop. They essentially wanted to create an economy run by the financial sector, making money by creating economic rent opportunities and deindustrialization.

The objective of finance capitalism is to make money quickly with the least effort possible. And that does not mean you invest in a factory and develop markets. You take over a factory or a corporation, break it up, deindustrialize, turn the office buildings or factories into gentrified housing. And you remove all of the taxes on economic rent, on land rent, on monopoly rent. Essentially, you create an economy that is overblown and in many ways is very much like the feudal economy—special interests, inherited rights, and the economy polarizes primarily by debt. And so this post-industrial capitalism has sort of created a new idea of economics as its advertising a public relations effort. And this neoclassical, anti-government economics says that the ideal of any economy is to make money quickly as it is measured in financial form. And what we’re seeing today in the United States is a huge upswing in the financial wealth of the 1% of the population, while the 99% of the population is running into debt.

So if you read the newspapers in the United States these days, it’s all about why don’t Americans realize what a wonderful thing that President Biden has done? The economy is doing wonderfully. Why do people say it’s not doing wonderfully? Why are they so unhappy with the economy? Well, the reason is it depends on who is the economy that you’re talking about. Are you talking about the economy for the 1% or the economy for the 99%? And the 1% are making money so rapidly at the expense of the 99% that overall wealth is actually going up? And so people think that the economy is doing good, but it’s a very polarized, concentrated economy, just the opposite of what industrial capitalism aimed at.

Michael Shilo DeLay

Steve, do you have a different perspective on the history? 

Steve Keen

Well, I want to try. I can see you trying to absorb what Michael was saying there, and it’s amazing to watch. A narrative will set how we think about a system, and Michael’s narrative—you know, I think I have much agreement with Michael was saying. There are elements I disagree with moderately. But the overall narrative Michael’s making is, you know, I think quite an accurate description of how capitalism, as it was originally saying, which was the industrial capitalism has been distorted into financial capitalism. And that has worked out very well for those who own the financial assets and extremely badly for those who work and to some extent extremely badly for those that manufacture as well.

So you do have that, I think, Michael, narrative is accurate, in other words. But I would also come back and say, well, what’s the original distinction of capitalism from feudalism or from socialism? And that starts off with the private ownership of the major production. Now, again, I’m not going to agree on that one, but what you get out of that is in a modern society, there’s no such thing as a perfectly private system, never, never existed. There’s always been a mixture of private and public. And the question under capitalism, what would work better? And if you ask what would be better in general what Michael was talking about, where the government provides health, education, wealth, and the infrastructure, etc., etc., that means that workers are paying, as he said, aren’t paying for the cost of transportation to make a profit for the owner of transportation.

They’re paying a lower cost. They’re getting free education. So the capitalists don’t need to educate them, etc., etc. And what you get therefore, is a higher profit for those manufacturers. But financial capital is very much based on their classical economic thinking is that neoclassical economics didn’t intend to be a defense for financial capital. But that’s what’s worked out. When I say deregulate, I mean remove controls on the finance sector. So therefore, I very much agree with Michael’s perspective overall. But I think we have to and say, well, you know, let’s look at the systemic level—feudalism versus capitalism, capitalism versus socialism. And the private ownership of the means of production is an essential part of that.

What you get—and this is in Michael’s narrative as well—is a large part of what is done by the powers that be. And in capitalism, that makes it work less well than if they hadn’t garage around with the system in the first place. And if you look back and say, what was the period where this is America’s reference point, American population was happiest and I’d say the happy days period, the 50s and 60s, which, you know, the Happy Days show, captured that. And you could have a single male worker most of the time supporting a large family and having plenty of leisure time relatively.

They didn’t have fancy things like this to talk on, conversations across the Internet, etc., etc., at the technological levels obviously lower, but you could support a family and have a reasonable family life and be working in an industrial setting as well. Have pride in what you are doing as a worker, etc., etc. So that’s not America today. And so a lot of the sense of misery people get, even though you will get neoclassical economists in particular saying, ‘Oh, they’re so much better off than they were back then,’ because look at the cars as I drive, you know, of let’s technological change and that side of capitalism is one worth discussing that’s the main distinguishing feature in one sense between a feudal period and a capitalist, you have a greater right of technological development during capitalism. And to some extent that benefits everybody. But you’ve had a breakdown.

Financial capital has undermined what made capitalism great for the period that it was. And that’s a large part of Michael’s argument. And I’ve seen the data on that, too. If you look at the level of private sector debt, you got the booms and busts of private debt. What drives the apparent wealth and the final poverty of capitalism? We are now in the period of the highest level of private debt in America’s history. And every time we get a high level of private debt like that, it’s, you know, the old joke about if you owe the bank $100, you have a problem; you have a problem for the bank a million dollars.

The bank has a problem. Well, we’ve ended up with a bank dominated because we are the billion the trillion dollars. And the dominance of the finance sector, I think, is what’s eroded the good side of capitalism. And that has been supported by conventional economic theory, even though they claim, of course, they’re not doing that.

Michael Hudson

Okay. Now, based on what Steve has said, I can see the question that should have been asked. What direction is capitalism going in? And we could have said what direction was industrial capitalism going in. Everybody in the 19th century said it’s going towards socialism. There were many kinds of socialism. And the whole argument in the last decade of the 19th century was what kind of socialism are we going to have? It’s obvious that instead of having a post feudal ruling class, a post feudal landlord class to collect rent, post feudal monopoly class and a predatory banking class, we’re going to have government playing an increasing role, including money creation and control of the credit system. So that was going towards socialism. There was a counter revolution, and that’s the revolution that we’ve been having for the last century towards neo classical neoliberal economics, and that’s finance capitalism, and that’s going in the direction that precisely what Steve just pointed out.

What is really growing under finance capitalism is finance is debt. And the debt of the population as a whole is credit on the opposite side of the balance sheet. So while people now are talking about the growth of debt and the debt problem. The debt problem has a twin on the other side of the balance sheet that grows proportionally. The debts of one group are the assets of another. So when Steve and I have both written about how the modern economic picture ignores debt and money because they say we owe the debt to ourselves, but who’s the ‘we’ and who is the ‘ourselves’? The debt that we owe, or the debt the 99% to ourselves, the 1%? So we’re really getting a narrative by the 1%. And it’s very largely a fictitious Orwellian doublespeak or narrative.

Anastasia Bendebury

Was this kind of transition away from the happy days of the 50s and 60s inevitable because there was more money in the world and there was a greater need to put it somewhere where it would continue to accrue? What accrued value?

Michael Hudson

That’s the kind of question an economist would ask you if you apologize for that comment. 

Anastasia Bendebury 

I am learning of total years for long enough.

Michael Hudson

Every economic tendency politicizes itself. And the problem is that the financial class gets richer, what does it do? It takes over government and it takes over policy making, especially in the United States. You privatized the election process by the Citizens United ruling where the nomination of political candidates is based on who can raise the most money from the donors. And so the head of every congressional committee, whether it’s the military or financing the heads of the financial committee and the members, are all received donations from the banks and the financial classes, the heads of the military committee. So get a subsidy by the military industrial complex. So this is the magic of the marketplace is political as well as just economic. That’s what has changed things.

The law has changed. The application of the law has changed. The culmination of finance capitalism peaked with President Obama, who had the largest bank fraud in American history and not a single bankster was sent to jail because the banksters nominate the judges. The banksters nominate the lawmaker. So you have economics is not simply the growth of debt or the growth of income. It’s a mode of economic power translates itself into political policy, regulation and who staffs the regulators?

Michael Shilo DeLay

It seems like the political aspects feed back upon the financial structures as well. With things like, you see, the rise of ESG is being priced into corporate decision making. Is there a feedback loop at play there as well, where politics start to drive some of the financial decisions?

Steve Keen

I’ll fight finance, roads, everything. I mean, we know the expression ‘the military-industrial complex’ that was actually coined by General Dwight D. Eisenhower, president-general. So, I think Eisenhower pretty much in his last day in office and he was a general and certainly see not just from the point of view of the president, but having been in the military himself, the extent to which the industrial complex generated the strength of the military sector and that ran American politics. What we have today, I think I call the financial-political complex.

The financial sector is the only part of the economy that has the ear of politicians. Politicians are persuaded by very self-serving arguments which, you know, look convincing, but they’re cut beneath them and they’re self-serving. And all the reforms, so-called, are about liberating finance. I just want to share, can I actually share my screen with you? Because I want to show some data because most people have got no awareness of the level of private debt in America and they try.

Anastasia Bendebury

Hold on. I have to change a couple things. Pardon the interruption, dear listeners, but we must ask you for a favor if you like what the Demystify side podcast does. Consider coming over to our Patreon. It is that patreon.com/demystifysci site and there you can contribute a couple of dollars a month to help us keep the ship running and allow us to continue our investigations into the most interesting ideas that are out there about nature, humans, history, the future, technology, economics, all of the things that we do on the podcast. In return for your donation, you get both of our episodes for the week early. You get to join our fantastic patron chat that meets weekly on Sunday mornings to talk about everything that is interesting in the world and the direction that the podcast should take. And you get to have the satisfaction of contributing to something that you think is important in the world.

If you can’t contribute right now, that is totally fine. We understand. I have been in that boat for many, many years. But what you can’t do without spending a single penny is come to our discord, come to our Facebook, come to our Twitter, come to our Instagram, like comment and subscribe. Because by helping us with the algorithm, you help us grow and really super passive way. And if you’ve already joined the patron, just do all that other stuff too. For now, back to the conversation.

Steve Keen

You’re going to see the top graph is the ratio of private debt to GDP in America from 1947 to today. Okay. And it starts about 50% of GDP back at the end of the Second World War, and then it just explodes cyclically, but it slows from 50% to 170% from the financial crisis in 2007 2008 occurred because the rate of growth of that debt turns from positive to negative. It went from a Ponzi scheme, the whole subprime thing, etc., etc. Ultimately, that fell over because people could miss a payment. Suddenly, they go bankrupt. And the growth of debt goes the opposite way, and drives house prices in the opposite direction. And you can see what I’ve done down here is I’ve taken the change in debt.

So this is the level of debt, which are the dollars we owe, that’s currently running at about $40 trillion, I think, in America’s current level. This is the annual change in debt that’s credit. The dollars per year that you borrow or the financial sector encourages you to take on as debt. And that peaked at over 15% of GDP just before the crisis began. It went down to minus five. Now, that’s repeating his part of history that’s been a part of America, right back to the 30s. You had the Great Depression, which was a more extreme version of this, and the panic of 1837, which was more extreme again. But the level of debt has never been as high as it is this time round. And that’s why we still live in a financial-loss economy. And the numbers scream it.

Now, what do you get out of mainstream economic theory as one of the. Well, this is the way in which Michael and I first bonded because we always approach the same issue from different directions. And we were about the only people and non-orthodox economists arguing the level of private debt mattered. And credit was driving the economy. And I remember, Michael, you remember this conversation. I’m sure I stayed in a hotel in a cabin in New York, and you came to visit me. And we were driving away in my hotel room, and you finally said to me, what is aggregate demand? And I answered, Now, technically, I’m slightly wrong here. I’ve since improved the argument. I answered it straight. They pay plus change in debt. And you said, why can’t other people see that? And it is, in fact, now what it is. Credit is part of aggregate demand and aggregate income. And I’ve proven that analytically as well.

So we now have the correct answer. If you leave credit out, if your analysis of aggregate demand in our program, you are not made whole in capitalism. And mainstream economics is lifted out all the way through and argues you don’t need to look at it. Now, that’s the reason I’ve done this bottom shot here, because the red line is the level of credit as a percentage of GDP mapped on the left-hand side of the chart. And the dotted line is the unemployment rate now. And that you can see, one goes up, the other goes down. Rising credit gives you falling unemployment, and vice versa. And the correlation between 1990 and 2015, which is the height of both the bubble, the burst, and then the aftermath. The correlation coefficient is greater than minus point nine. I ask was about point-out steroid.

Anastasia Bendebury

And so what and credit in this chart is just is personal debt that’s being carried by people or. 

Michael Hudson

Mortgage corporation.

Steve Keen 

Oh yeah, everything. It’s household debt and corporate debt of the of the non-financial sector to the banks. Okay, so it’s even worse when you look at the internal financials that the level is actually higher, but the data is badly designed. I just gave up on trying to include that data in my analysis, but this is how indebted the real economy is, so to speak, households and firms out of the financial sector. And because we’ve let the debt get this high, we’ve got you know it’s trebled, more than trebled.

So the happy days when debt was kept under control. And if you look at all the controls that came in after the Great Depression and the Second World War, they were to limit the capacity of the financial sector to do what they’d been allowed to do in the 50s, 60s, and out through to today. So we want to change financial capitalism because if you want to have a decent capitalism, you want industrial capitalism, not the financial sector going crazy. I’ll just I’ll stop my sharing now. But that’s you know, it isn’t just words. In other words, we’re both good talkers, Michael. Better than me. We’re both good talkers, which we’re a good pair. 

Michael Hudson

But we’re best when we talk to each other and we bounce ideas off each other.

Steve Keen

Yeah. The data screamingly supports us. I mean, I used to teaching it before I met Michael. I was working over in the University of Western Sydney in Australia, and I was first starting to look at this information, and I would say to my students. I wouldn’t dare make up the numbers that I actually find in the statistics. If I was trying to make the case that I believe. In other words, the data is overwhelmingly stronger than I would dare to pretend it was if I didn’t actually know the data. And so Michael and I went with that, led the battle in non-Orthodox economics.

I have got to focus upon the financial capital. The level of private debt and its effects and they have caught up with us to some degree. But, you know, we definitely led the battle on that front. And it means that, you know, we understand that capitalism, which we have now, is a perverted version of what it started as and what it should have stayed. And Marx actually put it beautifully. This is in I think it’s in the third volume of capital. I said talk about centralization, the banks and the money lenders, and the parasites that surround him.

Occasionally, got the capacity to dominate the industrial capitalism. And this gang knows nothing about production and should have nothing to do with it. And he called them the roving Cavaliers of Credit. And that is what we’ve let take over. And Marx was right in that if you’d had much better capitalism, we would never have got the garbage we have got now. He had a naive vision of what socialism would be, but he would have kept the financial sector under control. And that’s what we need to do to have a decent version of capitalism.

Michael Shilo DeLay

It occurs to me that there’s the sort of false dichotomy set up in most people’s minds which regards the division between capitalism and socialism. But what we’re talking about is the nuances of government restraints on the different industrial and financial sectors. Like there’s a more nuanced dichotomy that should be at the center of people’s attentions. 

Michael Hudson

Well, the answer is yes. And Steve points out that he and I are almost the only people that continue to talk not only about debt, but the fact that the economy cannot recover until you cancel the debt. Well, the reason that economists don’t want to talk about debt, if they’re representing the status quo is the old phrase, the devil wins at the point that people believe he doesn’t exist. The financial sector winds at the point where people think debt doesn’t matter. Debt problems don’t exist. Don’t regulate it.

There’s nothing to see here, folks. Keep on moving. What I should have said is that in does at the very beginning is that industrial capitalism ends at creating profits, and it creates profits by employing labor to sell at a profit. And making profits means minimizing economic rent and minimizing predatory finance. Finance capitalism doesn’t look for profits. That’s why we’re deindustrialization.

It looks at economic rent-seeking and financial gains. So the objective of these two forms of capitalism are diametrically opposite. And if you look at where they’re going, this really is the problem. Are we going to have a society based on profits and wages and rising feedback between rising wages, higher productivity, and higher capital investment? Or are we going to have the finance capitalism just looking at how to get a free lunch at the economy’s expense?

Anastasia Bendebury

I don’t know if you saw this World Economic Forum presentation where, at the end of it, they made this point that, in the future, you will own nothing and be happy. And it’s really stuck with me because it feels like there is a massive force. That’s kind of pressing on the lever arm of society to push people towards dematerializing their own lives, where…. 

Michael Hudson

I guess they have the Obama doctrine now. When he came here after the 2008 crisis, he said, we’re going to start with nobody owning anything by evicting 10 million American families that have been fraudulently loaded down with junk mortgages. Let’s first of all, reduce owner a land homeownership by the black and Hispanic population. Let’s slash homeownership. And you’ve had since the Obama takeover, financial takeover, a plunge of ten percentage points in America’s homeownership rate. Yes, we’re moving towards the polarization, moves towards nobody will own anything, meaning nobody except the 1%. Well, on anything.

Steve Keen

But this what what we’re caught up in, as well as a battle between reality and ideology. And ideology, is neoclassical economic theory and people who swallow it’s arguments all the way through. And if you go back to the 70s and 80s, that was when you had the real switch shift from a Keynesian understanding, which is like a bastardized version of a Marxian understanding which at least appreciated classes exist and at least appreciated. You wanted to get income to the working class because the working class will spend faster than the richer.

So if you actually distribute money to the working class, it ends up going to the capitalists anyway ultimately. And you get, and this is actually what’s called a classic is profit equation that says that if all you increase government spending ends up in the pockets of capitalists because you give it to workers, they’ll spend it, and it ends up in WalMart, etc., etc.

Now, the thing is, if you do that, that’s better than giving it to the capitalists directly, although certainly financial capital, they spend much more slowly. So what do you get out of it? Is even though, you know, it ends up being something which capitalists profit from, you get a better level of economic activity, a larger level of economic activity. If the goes through the workers in the first place, workers have to spend the money they’ve got very rapidly, capitalists and the bankers spend it very slowly, and they’ve got far more money.

So what’s happened is a switch to the money going to the workers, which gave us the buoyant economy of the 50s and 60s, that the happy days capitalism, where it goes to the ultra wealthy now and they buy now. They used to buy Lamborghinis, now they buy top-level Teslas. They’ve got yachts everywhere. They compete over the size that they also have got. It’s a much, much more, as I said earlier, a feudal-type economy we’ve generated. And the point I want to make, I’m going to share my screen again. By the way, this is a very heavy-looking piece of data here.

But one of the things which was sold to get a change, like we’ve got out of Thatcher and and Reagan, you’ve got to have something which gets the popular support so you get people voting for it. Part of that comes out of the Murdochs of the world pushing their views and so on. But what they were saying is get rid of trade unions, get rid of government interference, get rid of, you know, socialized medicine, and socialize education. And what we’re going to get is a booming economy that grows much faster. And even though you won’t have a welfare state holding your hand or putting a net beneath you, you’re going to have a faster rate of growth. You’ll be wealthier. Okay.

So what that tells you is their argument was the economy would grow faster if we moved from the. Type of capitalism Michael was talking about earlier, where the government covered a lot of those costs, to one where everything is privatized. That was supposed to increase the rate of economic growth. Now, I could show a screen. Was it worth trying again?

Michael Shilo DeLay

Yeah. You should be good to go.

Steve Keen

I think we got it. Give it a try. Okay, Just hang on a second. Let’s share the same score. This is my software package. Ravel. By the way, Michael the Terminator. A lot of the shots on this one. But I want to just zoom in to show you the growth.

 

Steve Keen

Rate makes it all clear.Okay.

Steve Keen

So, what you can see, this is for America. And the growth rate from 1945 to 1975 was 3.24, roughly 3.25% per annum. Real economic growth for 75 has been 1.9%. Okay. That’s virtually halving the rate of growth, which of course means that the level of economic activity now for many, many years is far lower than it would have been if we continued with the old, so-called inefficient Keynesian system. So they’ve sold us a product. We’ve bought the pump. And the trouble is, nobody realizes. Let’s say I’ve got a few bucks for the stock, but I’ll try going to another country here. Let’s try Japan, for example, and see if I can upload the data.

Anastasia Bendebury

Well, while you’re working that out, I wonder. So if the switch to financial capital has been this artificial method by which to grow GDP by seeking rent from, you know, the working class, why doesn’t the growth of GDP reflect that calculation? Like, why does it slow down?

Steve Keen 

The growth of GDP to growth, of ownership of capital, ownership of resources, and a concentration of wealth? So we’ve actually grown more slowly. If you go the money to the workers and they were spending on Happy Days form, there’d be a higher rate of economic growth. That’s what they told us they’d get. They didn’t get the higher rate of growth. We’re now slumping, but they’re much, much wealthier, and we’re all complaining about it, and we’re right and they’re wrong. Michael

Michael Hudson

Well, two things about that. When President Biden gave money for the Covid people, I guess that was President Trump who did that. The workers used their money to pay down their credit card debt because what’s brewing is debt. You’ve talked about the growth of GDP. And what’s happened is that finance capitalism transforms the concept of GDP; it erases the distinction between what is the product and what is overhead. For instance, right now in America, as a result of this, growing death, arrears and foreclosures are increasing for housing, for automobiles and for credit card debt. Defaults of loans are rising.

Now, what happens when you default on a credit card loan? Your interest rate goes up from 19% a year to about 30% a year. And this the credit card companies now make more money and penalties than they make in interest. And what they make in penalties is recorded in the GDP is providing financial services. So the more you lose your money, you lose your house. You pay higher financial rates. This is considered economic growth, not overhead. And all of the money, the high wages that our CEOs pay themselves, the monopoly prices that are charged for Amazon and for the other companies are under federal prosecution right now for big monopolies. All of this is economic growth. What is growing is the financial tumor, not the economy as a whole, not the industrial economy. Again. That’s why the US economy is deep industrializing. And they call that economic growth because the financial sector is making a fortune off deindustrialization.

Steve Keen

And this is actually a problem with how the the flow of funds tables are defined way back in the in the 40s which Copeland, who designed the statistician Michael, and I both have a lot of respect for. But the mistake he made was he decided to record industrial capitalism. You can report the number of cars going out the factory door times the price. If you get a physical measure of the profit, you go the capital, you purchase the machinery, you’ve got all these prices, and it’s all solid and real. But how do you call it the finance sector? And he decided simply to call the contribution of the finance sector’s GDP the sum of the finance sector.

All the wages that are paid, all the bonuses, all the profits that are that are made. So if you pay double the pay of a CEO, you increase their they pay. Now, that’s wrong. We should have said, let’s look at it and say one of my students way, way back at my university, western Sydney, put it better. He said, Is finance a profit center or a cost? And the answer is it’s cost of doing business. It’s not a profit center. We have made the mistake of saying it was being creative. And therefore, and that’s also, unfortunately, the way the companies often does accounts rather than having a negative for the financial sector, which would have made sense.

You made it a positive, as if it adds to profit, adds to GDP. And what has happened? Of course, it’s grown enormously. So the financial sector is going for something of the order of. I don’t have the exact numbers, but say like about 5% of GDP to 15% of GDP. And we’ve counted that as growth. But as Michael said, it’s not a growth. It’s a tremor past a certain level. You do need finance to enable, you know, all the transactions that we do on a daily basis. And you need borrowed money if you’re going to buy a large item like a house or a car, etc., etc. It does make sense to have a certain level of financial debt in a capitalist economy, but not three times what it was in the 50s.

Michael Hudson

And then this financial bias is the denial that there is any such thing as economic rent. Post-Industrial capitalism theory says everybody earns whatever income they get. So, as I think I said it on the earlier broadcast on our show, when the head of Goldman Sachs says, our partners are the most productive workers in the American economy. Look at how much our partners are paid.

As we rob companies, pull them apart, create international crimes by stealing Malaysia’s foreign money, the most money is to be made in crime. We know that. And we’re the best criminals. There are financial criminals, which is why they were prosecuted. Well, if you say that everybody earns what they get, no matter how they earn it, there is no such thing as unearned income, no economic rent. Then you you’ve negated the entire 19th-century political economy.

All of the value and price theory of the 19th century that was the essence of industrial capitalism was to distinguish earned from unearned income so that they could free capitalism from the landlord class, from the monopolies, and from the predatory bankers, and the counterrevolution that began a century ago and in which we are still living, denies this distinction. So that again, the devil has made himself invisible.

Steve Keen

You look back at Ricardo because people would know Ricardo for the theory of comparative advantage. Now, that was one of the can I call it the shows. And Patrick, because he managed to deceive everybody. And the Economist that that’s been the one, the one horse, the one trick pony that economist economics have been since is using the idea of specialization. But what his real purpose for putting that argument forward was that he argued that workers get the means of subsistence.

Capitalists you want they want capital to get a profit. Those capitalists will invest. And if you want to had a longer period of growth before what he saw as being a stationary site in the future, then you want to get as much money into the hands of the capitalist. So go in this and as little as possible. And so the landlords. So if you read him carefully, he says, My purpose in this book has been to show GW to show that wherever.

Rents go down, profits go up effectively. And I haven’t got the quote right there. But what he’s saying, if he can reduce the amount that goes to rent, you’ll get a higher rate of growth and you’ll have a longer period of prosperity before the stationary state. So he was anti-landlord, which is hilarious because he actually was a landlord. But nonetheless, that was the flavor of Smith. It was the flavor.

Ricardo certainly, Marx’s on the whole idea was to minimize raunchier behavior. And if you look back and see what the feudal system was, that was the ultimate of frontier behavior. So that’s where the anti-feudal, pro-capitalist elements exist in all the classical schools, and the neo-classical had this fantasy view of capitalism to begin with. But they’re the ones who threw away the distinction. And then that, of course, very much suited the wealthy. And so, Michael, you probably know a lot more about this than I do.

But the takeover of economics in the 1870s, from the classical school to the neoclassical school, where virtually in about a decade you went from the classical school being the dominance and the neoclassical being the undergrowth to all the professors of economics being a neo classical.

Michael Hudson

So it was largely in the 1890. John Bates Clark in America, and similar the Austrians abroad, it was a whole counter-revolution. That’s basically what you had? 

Steve Keen

Yeah. And that meant we went from a generally fairly realistic picture of capitalism under the classical school of economic thought and then one that ends up with the type of capitalism we had in the 50s and 60s, which was largely an accident, more than deliberate, to the financial capital side. And the neoclassical economic theory justifies all that by saying that the ludicrous pay being paid to manage people, managing financial organizations because they have a high marginal product. Well, since capitalism a meritocracy, which is bullshit.  

Steve Keen

Well, since Steve mentioned Ricardo, well, when our generation went to school, they still taught the history of economic thought that is now stripped away from the curriculum. The one thing they don’t teach is that there ever was a theory of economic rent. They don’t talk about Ricardo or the whole 19th century.

They’ve replaced the history of economic thought with mathematics, as if you can just mathematics. The existing statistics that have all been, as Steve pointed out, restructured so as to deny that there’s any distinction between the financial economy and real industry. So you have economists being turned out that are very smart mathematically, but they don’t know what to be smart about because they’ve never been exposed to the idea that there is such a thing as economic rent, unearned income, and debt crises.

Anastasia Bendebury

So I want to talk about the way that….  

Steve Keen

I wouldn’t call them smart.

Michael Hudson

Clever. What shall we say? Oh, idiot. Savants.

Anastasia Bendebury

Numerate. They very numerous. 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Quantitatively reasonable.

Anastasia Bendebury

Quantitatively able.

Michael Hudson

Sounds as if Robert McNamara was running the economy like you ran the war.

Anastasia Bendebury

I want to understand better why debt is so stifling. Because in the back of my mind, I’m kind of like, Well, why can’t it just continue to go on eternally? Like, why can’t we just have this thing?

Michael Shilo DeLay

About national debt.

Anastasia Bendebury

National debt, personal debt, economic debt, Just like, why can’t it just perpetually grow and grow and grow? And if everybody’s debt is growing and everybody’s kind of looking at it and is like, well, it’s just that’s just that’s just the thing that grows fine.

Steve Keen

It’s growing faster than everything else. This is the problem. If debt grew at the same rate of GDP, we wouldn’t be having this conversation. And government debt is different. So that’s the point worth elaborating on shortly. But private debt, a private debt was growing up faster.

Today, probably the same ratio, and therefore, you’d be right; it could continue growing. What we’re talking about, the ratio has grown dramatically. And then, what’s happened? It’s gone from being a servant of capitalism to a parasite of capitalism. And it’s slowed down the capacity of the industrial capitalism to develop new products. And like the first example we ever saw, that was actually Japan, because if you go back to the postwar period for Japan, you got the enormous Japanese miracle, as they call it. Dramatic growth in the economy. And then, between 1980 and 1990, they had what they called, they literally call it the bubble economy. Where people were speculating on the value of houses in in Tokyo so that the Imperial Palace, which I think has got an area about ten square kilometers roughly. Maybe less than that was worth more than California.

Steve Keen

You had the Nikkei reach almost 40,000 points on the 31st of December, 1989. It since fell to about 7000 points. But this financial bubble took over. Now, up until that point, up to 1990, you would see movies like what was it called The Rising Sun. A classical that was Denzel Washington was adorable. A very classic movie about Japan taking over everything. And we had Walkmans, etc., etc. What happened?

Well, Japanese corporations tended to operate as connected with the church. So rather than being equity-financed, they were largely debt financed. There was a symbiotic relationship, but also independent at the same time. Well, those Japanese corporations have so much debt that they’ve spent most of the period since 1990 paying off that debt. And the industrial development, the technological development that we associated with Japan died in the US. And so that’s what got rid of them. And wait.

Anastasia Bendebury

Who did they owe their debt to?

Steve Keen

But the Japanese cooperation under two Japanese banks, the level of private debt in Japan went from about 30% of GDP and sort of fairly flat for quite some time through the 70s and 80s. Rose 225% of GDP. And then, after the crisis, and now back down to about the same level as America, which is about 170% of GDP. So when you let that get out of hand, you stall. You stifle everything in the real economy. Investment. Technological development and happiness.

Michael Hudson

This can easily be charted. You have the key for financial debt that grows by compound interest. I can send you that. And while the economy grows an S-curve, it tapers off. And the reason it tapers off. As debt grows at compound interest, there is a gap. And more and more of the output of wages and profits have to be paid to the creditors is interest. And the more you pay in interest and amortization to the creditor class, the less you have to pay on goods and services. This is the most sophisticated mathematical model of this, was in Babylonia in 1750 B.C. The Babylonians had a very clear model. Because we have, what are the textbooks that they taught for their scribes? They asked, How fast does a debt grow at a compound interest?

Well, at 20%, every debt doubles in five years. It quadruples in ten years and multiplies eightfold in 15 years and on. But the economy they have, how fast does a herd of cattle grow? And they have a tapering off. And when modern translators first looked at these, they thought, Oh, this must be just actual statistics. But they actually taught it in the model that the rate of debt exceeds the ability to pay. So what what do you do with such a model? Well, it’s very simple.

Hammurabi wiped out all of the personal debts four times during his rule. Not commercial debts. Commercial debts owed by businesses to each other stayed in place. But you need a debt write down. If you look at the statistics that Steve just put up on the growth of debt, the only way in which you can prevent this debt from causing a chronic depression, what Irving Fisher called debt deflation in the 1930s, is to write down the debt.

Well, if you look at today with a former head of the Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke, was given the Nobel Prize for saying that there’s no such thing as debt deflation. Irving Fisher was wrong. So they give the Nobel Prize. They think if we give enough prizes to idiots savants who mislead the economy, then we can maybe people will think if they have a prize, they’re a celebrity and they know why listen to Steve and Michael, who are never going to get the Nobel Prize. Because if they gave us the Nobel Prize, they’d have to cancel all the prizes they’ve given for the last 50 years.

Steve Keen

And the Nobel Prize—I don’t know if you guys know this is not a Nobel Prize. Are you aware of that?

Michael Hudson

Yes.

Anastasia Bendebury

In what’s important ?

Steve Keen

I’ll go to Congress. Why ask a Nobel? Alfred Nobel established the prize in chemistry, physics, literature. And I think it was those four prizes, not economics. And I actually specifically considered and said it wasn’t a science. It shouldn’t be given a prize. In 1969, the Swedish central bank, which it was fighting headed by neoclassical economists, was fighting a battle to prevent the social democratic politics that we tend to still associate with Sweden. And they came up with the idea of having a prize, which this call I can’t pronounce the name of the bank in Swedish.

The Swedish Central Bank Prize in Economics in honor of Alfred Nobel 1969. That’s when it started. Everybody there selected by a few as a handful of many rebels. So that I can sort of button down dispute occasionally. But it’s been to strengthen the neoclassical vision all the way through.

Michael Shilo DeLay

So it strikes. Me as a bigger problem, too, with Nobel Prizes, which is, how do you walk back on something like, you know, science in general knowledge? The acquisition of knowledge is always changing. The way we see things is changing. And I don’t know how you that’s kind of one of the dangers of giving these monumental prizes—that you don’t have the ability to change your mind anymore, which is really dangerous to progress.

Steve Keen

We can’t withdraw a prize. I think there should, if it was possible, withdraw prize. The two prizes almost want to withdraw a William Nordhaus Prize in 2009 for the so-called comics of climate change. I only read his shit, and that’s my technical description of what he wrote. I only read his shit after he got the prize and realized how bad it was. I’d read Bernanke’s before the prize when I saw that, given that guy’s been given the prize for an approach model, a model of lending, which the Bank of England said is garbage, In 2014, the Bundesbank said his garbage. In 2007 time, literature said the textbooks are wrong, and they give a price to this guy. Five years later, after the Bundesbank. Yeah. So it is just a sign of how it’s an ideology. It’s not a science.

Michael Hudson

But that’s why it’s given, and that’s why it’s named for a Nobel. Nobel invented dynamite, which is how I made the fortune to support it. The Nobel Prize is for intellectual dynamite. It blows up the understanding of the economy to leave devastation in its wake.

Anastasia Bendebury

Per Nobel.. I want to understand something about the way that profits become accumulated at the peak of the credit structures. Because we were talking about the way that debt grows and the financial system makes most of its profits off of servicing that debt. And I guess I’m trying to understand what actually happens to the money that’s accumulating there.

Like, does it get paid out of salaries? Does it just live in the bank and then allow the bank to then progressively ratchet up its influence on the economy, or, like, what happens ? Like, if it’s debt and it’s being calculated as part of the economy and somebody is accumulating it, Is it real wealth that’s getting spent, or is it just sitting on a ledger somewhere being accounted for but not being used? 

Michael Hudson

Oh, you love to ask trick questions. What they count as profit is what anybody earns, whether they earn it or it’s unearned economic rent, financial, let’s say revenue, which is the word that the classical economists used, the financial revenue. What the banks do, they relend it and yet more debt.

That’s why debt grows exponentially. All of the revenue of the banking financial sector earns is reinvested in yet more debt to invest in debt. the economy yet more, siphoning off yet more revenue from the from industry and from wage earners. So there’s even less and less and less money to spend on the goods and services that they produce. And you create economic shrinkage. So if not industrial profit that grow, it’s the profits of the ranters and the monopolists. And if you don’t believe there’s any such thing as economic rent or monopoly rent or landlord rent, or financial rent, then to you, it’s all the same thing. There’s no distinction at all.

Anastasia Bendebury

Can we break apart the distinction between economic, financial landlords? Like all of these different types of rents?

Michael Hudson

What they have in common is their unearned, and as John Stuart Mill said, landlords make their rent in their sleep. Well, so do financial investors who hold bonds for mortgages. They make their rent without enterprise, without earning. They play no role in the process of production, employment and reinvestment, and economic growth. They say they simply obtain a special privilege, a monopoly privilege, the privilege of being a creditor. And instead of having the government as the creditor, as you have in China. And as long as you are unearned.

Michael Shilo DeLay

But surely there is a role for rent, right? There must be a role. I mean, when kids come out of the house at 18, they’re not to be able to afford a house under any economic structure that I can imagine. So do you imagine?

Steve Keen

There’s a role for rental. But you also constrain it that there’s a role for debt. But you have to constrain it. Michael’s point earlier about the same area, and Michael knows this. This is his power, his expertise, not mine. But what you had in that vision was we had an agricultural society. You had physical bounds on your plots. So if you stop farming somewhere, you’re going to reach the boundaries at some point. But if you’re borrowing and you’ve got to pay really high compound interest, that’s going to rise exponentially. And what happened? We’re telling Michael’s work, so pardon me, mine. I want to just elaborate only on your idea.

The debts of financial of corporate debt, people doing trading. That wasn’t abolished. That was left as it was because that was a corporate decision. But most of these debts run up in made holes, or they were run up with values of crops, and so on. And there were such high rates of interest, they’d necessarily grow faster than the productivity of the fields that were actually supporting it. Now, the downside for the emperor at that stage was only free men could fight in the army. So the more debt that occurred, the more people became wage slaves and began work on the land as the landlord. And if that continued long enough, there’d be no army to fight all the other empires. And you’d collapse.

So there was a strong reason for the state to come in and say, we’re going to abolish those debts. You could go back as been very free men back on the land you lost because of the debts you ran up in the middle or through failed harvests. And you’d replenish and regenerate. And if you look at this again as Michael’s work, you look at the history of human civilization from way back those 3000 years, B.C., right through the Roman period to today, a huge part of what we see in all sorts of great men theories of conflict have really been struggle between debtors and creditors and the political power now and the hand of the creditors. And that’s what gives you a society which ultimately undermines itself. And that’s what we’re seeing now.

Anastasia Bendebury

So it sounds like you’re saying that if we bring back debtors prisons and we imprison the large majority of people that have debt, all of the sudden we’ll create the incentive structure for canceling the debt because there’s literally not going to be anybody to work any more people.

Steve Keen

If you cancel that in jail, I mean, yeah, you would. But it is the extent to which political power rests with those who want the money. And if you let them, then they are their own worst enemies in the long run. So even though they’re dominating the 1% or the .01 percent, really, they’re the ones who are benefiting out of the current system. Their decisions about how to run it are undermining its viability.

Michael Hudson

Well, the problem is that the financial sector doesn’t have a long run. They live in the short run. It’s the hit-and-run that’s the problem. They don’t care about the long run. They’ll say, Well, we’ll do something else. When we wreck this economy, they’ll move on to another. And you can see this most of all in the international economy: the global South debt, a dollar debt. How is it ever going to be paid? All of this was debated in the 1920s with German reparations and allied debts, and all of that’s been expunged from the economics curriculum. And I went all the way through a Ph.D. without ever hearing a word about a debt or the debt crisis. It’s not talked about in polite company.

Anastasia Bendebury

Yes, that’s something that I wanted to go into, which is the eventual pressure, not just on a bank on its own people, but this gradual push towards the bank, pressuring other countries and affecting their ability to make freely self-determined choices. And it seems like an extension of just resource extraction because the terms of the loans are often extortionist. And so one generation agrees to the term of the loans. Another generation is paying it off, and it promotes poverty and the ability to just extract the wealth from a country. That is agreed to something that maybe it didn’t really understand to begin with or was forced to.

Michael Hudson

Since we’ve talked a lot about global warming. Before I talk about Third World debt, I want to talk about why neo liberal has lives and has a financial center, and it’s America, and America’s balance of control over the international economy is very much by control of the oil industry. The financial sector makes loans to whatever sector can afford to pay the most interest back and the most. I won’t say profitable.

The most rent-intensive sector is the oil sector. Every dollar of oil investment abroad is repaid, and balance of payments terms in 18 months. At least that’s what I. I found in the only study of the oil industry that’s been done. So the one of the aims and objectives is finance. And finance capitalism is to speed up global warming and to control the world economy by being able to turn off any country’s oil, electricity, and economic power, and hence its growth of GDP as well as warming houses. It will, if it can, control the oil trade.

That’s why the United States blew up the pipelines with Russia. If the United States can control the oil trade of the world, then it can essentially have a stranglehold on the economy. And that’s why the United States prime aim and diplomacy is there. We will disable any attempt to slow global warming, accelerating global warming. preventing an alternative to oil, gas, and coal is a key to America’s ability to control the world economy. And Steve has done all the numbers on that.

Steve Keen

Well, I mean, I got blame particular Americans, not just America in general for global warming, but William, the White House, being one of the main ones. I can’t think of the guy’s name, but a physicist as well who worked for the government and talked the government out of worrying about global warming back in the 80s the 70s and 80s, which is why America’s done nothing about it. But yeah, again, this is a point of the short-term bigness of capitalism, why that’s so damn dangerous.

But the financial sector in particular, because they’re all on three-month reporting at best, they look five years in the future. And I’m speaking from personal experience here and that I’ve written a report called Loading the Dice Against Pensions, which points out the extent to which neoclassical economics in the form of William Law, White Houses models, and all the models that have been generated around by his cabal of neoclassical economists trivialized the dangers of climate change with the worst research I’ve ever seen in my life. Okay.

Dreadful, dreadful stuff should never have been published. But the impact of the sanctions is pointing out how badly these pension funds have been advised by consultants who relied upon their economic research. The barrier I’ve come up against to say, Well, yeah, but that’s outside our investment horizon. That’s more than five years in the future. Now, if civilization is going to be destroyed in six years, that’s outside their investment horizon.

Anastasia Bendebury

I wouldn’t like civilization to be destroyed in six years, though I would expect that there would be a perpetual loops. I would expect that there would be a perpetual decay that you see in advance. And so if you look at your five-year window and it starts to just trend down for the next, you know, for the last ten, five-year windows, then you’re looking at the decay. And is that kind of how they used to justify.

Steve Keen

No, they just it’s even if it doesn’t affect their current profit and loss statements and the three reporting and five year reporting and so on, then they’re not going to be bothered about it. Now with that means that you only start realizing, oh, global warming is affecting us; we should do something about it when it’s too late.

You can’t have that time horizon to survive something of the nature of global warming. And economists applied an enormous role in trivializing the dangers. And when capitalism collapses, and I’m using when not if, when capitalism collapses, it’ll be the fault of economists, neoclassical economists, not the radicals. So people are going to bring capitalism down. They’re the ones who thinkers who think they’re its friends.

Anastasia Bendebury

So when you say that capitalism collapses, what do you see near feudalism or you see something totally different?

Steve Keen

Mad Max.

Anastasia Bendebury

I mean, that’s very romantic. But..

Steve Keen

Now it’s not romantic. But I’m looking forward to dying before it happens. I mean, I can’t if you keep having watched Covid in particular and seeing the catastrophe that our so-called leaders made of that, if you didn’t have experts at all in charge of anything at any point when you had idiots like Boris Johnson, who’s being exposed in a Covid inquiry in the UK right now, the stupidity of the decisions that were made to imagine that we’re going to realize there’s a threat and then organize collectively and do the right thing and just manage to save ourselves in the nick of time is a Hollywood movie. It ain’t going to happen.

Michael Hudson

What is happening is that the world is now dividing into two halves. You have the golden billion, the garden of the Anglo-Saxon world, Europe, and America, and you have the jungle. That’s how they had to borrow at the European Union Express as the jungle as the 75% of humanity.

China, Russia, Iran, the BRICs, plus countries. So they are the groups led by China that are moving towards socialism. And what makes China so uniquely different from the capitalist countries is they have kept money creation and banking, and credit in as a public utility in the government’s hands. So in America, when a corporation goes bankrupt, it’s closed down, it’s sold and dismantled. In China, if you’re the creditor, China is the one country where it’s politically possible to cancel the debts without a creating a political crisis, because you can’t if you’re the government; you’re canceling debts owed to yourself. It’s always easier to cancel the debts owed to themselves, which is why Hammurabi in Babylonia was able to write them down, because the palace and the temples were the creditors, not a privatized financial class. So the privatized the financial class in the West is the it has essentially replaced the landlord class, the great the major source of debt and credit is now mortgage loans in the West. 80% of American and British loans are mortgage loans for real estate.

So there isn’t a landlord class anymore. But still, land rent is created a rent-seeking class. Although it’s a rent-seeking financial class, not a landlord class. But in China has the ability to right now cope with the fact that its real estate prices are also collapsing. But it doesn’t have to evict the homeowners.

It can just either write down the debts or it can let the private banks that are borrowed from the Central Bank of China and lend out money to the big real estate companies like Evergrande and Country Garden that have overbuilt; it can let the banks go under. And the good thing about letting the banks go under is you wipe out all of the large depositors. You move towards equalizing the income. And that is the beauty of canceling the debt: you cancel the savings of this predatory 1% financial class that you want to, so you get your benefit, the debtors, and you benefit society by removing the creditors from their position of trying to take power and dismantle governments, attempt to regulate them, and create an overall prosperity.

Michael Shilo DeLay

Is there any modern precedent for debt cancellation?

Michael Hudson

Yes. The 3000 years of every near Eastern ruler, not only Sumerian, but Babylonian, every near Eastern Kingdom, even Assyria, cancel the debts and that. Well, the Babylon.

Anastasia Bendebury

MichaeI, I know you’re older than us, but I feel like Sumerian. Babylonia is a fair example of modernity. That kids…

Michael Shilo DeLay

Yeah. What would what would the modern version of that look like? Like, how would that even unfold? Who would have the power to pull that off?

Michael Hudson

The Germany’s economic miracle in 1948 when they wiped out all debt except for the debt that employers owed their employees for the last week or, you know, a month or two. And everybody was allowed to keep a few thousand marks and in the bank. So the Germany wrote down the debt because most of the creditors were Nazis and the debts are owed to the Nazis. So it’s easy when you don’t treat the Nazis. The problem is that we don’t treat Goldman Sachs and Chase Manhattan as financial Nazis, and we’re not willing to write down the debts owed to them, as the allies were willing to write down the German debts in 1948 that started the economic miracle.

Steve Keen

Michael and I’ve been pushing this point for decades now that if you want to get capitalism function well, you reduce private debt. Okay? That’s the private debt and unearned income of the two things you want to minimize to enable capitalism to grow. And it’s done by accident for the Germans after World War Two. And that was in reaction to what the disaster they caused when they did the opposite after World War One. So that’s the Marshall Plan was the last time America acted with intelligence in the international sphere. And then the benefits that were huge.

Now we’re trying to say the same thing. You could actually reduce private debt by using the government’s capacity to create money and cancel private debts in what I call the modern deterrable. And I’ve done the modeling and all this, and Michael and I’ve spent a long time discussing it. The idea was should give everybody an equal amount of money, which means I’d get the same amount of money as Rupert Murdoch. Okay. And then, if you had any debt, you’d have to pay it down. If you didn’t have any debt, you’d get a cash injection, which you could make to spend, or you could have controls over it in terms of asset ownership if you didn’t want to cause a huge inflationary surge. And if you did that, you’d reduce the level of private debt dramatically.

Government debt can be carried out easily. And when I’ve stimulated it, government debt also falls ultimately because the rate of turnover of money rises so much because workers suddenly have money without debt, so they can suddenly spend. You got a greater level of economic growth coming out of it. So you address the debt ratio over time as well. So it’s quite feasible to do it, and it’ll never happen because if only America’s armies could only be staffed by people who didn’t have debt, then maybe America would agree to cancel household and private debt. Otherwise, it couldn’t invade other countries. But unfortunately, that’s not the case.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Wouldn’t the banks collapse if you canceled private debt? Because, I mean, a lot of the banks are…

 

Steve Keen

A lot of them have to sack a lot of workers earning ridiculous salaries. So it wouldn’t be a bad thing to go and get a factory job.

 

Michael Hudson

The banks would be good as they did under Roosevelt. There’d be a bank holiday. They’d reopen the next day. But the uninsured depositors, the billionaires, would no longer have their money. And again, that’s a good thing. Not a bad thing, because they haven’t used their billions of dollars very well.

 

Steve Keen

I’ve actually I don’t model that happening. I model that everybody gets the same amount of money. Money doesn’t get destroyed. You have the same amount of money, which you end up backing. The money, rather than being backed by private debt, is backed by government money-creation capability. You go from credit-based money to state-based money. You could leave the same amount of money in their own overall system. But by reducing the debt on a per capita basis, you’d benefit the poor far more than you benefit the rich. And that’s the idea behind it.

I want us to negotiate politically palatable. You could actually sell it to 90% of the population that are off. The trouble is, you simply can’t get this law discussed. Idea discussed anywhere in any circles apart from like when Michael and I get together. It just it is not even discussed. And economic theory is a major reason why. Because you if you try to argue to Ben Bernanke that you should reduce the level of debt, oh, pure redistribution should have no significant macroeconomic effects. That’s from the paper. After he got the paper right after the one he got the Nobel Prize for. You know, so economic theory is what’s preventing a sensible reform of capitalism. And in terms of the global warming, it’s what setting us up for the physical demise of capitalism, as it’s climate change destroys sedentary civilizations. So, you know, the greatest enemy of capitalism is neoclassical economics.

 

Michael Hudson

Think of it as a debt pollution. And that pollution is like environmental pollution that grows and grows and grows and stifles growth.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

But I’m still thinking about it in terms of just how much money you would have to actually pay people. I was looking at this recently. The average personal debt in the United States is $30,000. And that’s like for every man, woman, and … 

 

Michael Hudson

The 50% of Americans don’t have any savings at all. That’s the key. Let’s look at who has the savings. If you always look at both sides of the balance sheet, if you think of economics in terms of balance sheets, not just one side, you’ll get the basic dynamics. When you talk about debt. Also, look at savings. 50% don’t have any savings. And the average American can only raise $400 in an emergency, according to the Federal Reserve statistics. So you know what happens when there is an emergency there? They go further and further into debt because they can’t pay for it. And that’s really the problem that we’re in. So it’s not the amount of money, the what a lot of money is. The savings of the 1% is the concentration clotting at the top of the economic pyramid.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

I mean, I just looked it up. The average household debt, as reported by The Motley Fool at the end of 2022, was $100,000.

 

Michael Hudson

But most of that would be up real estate debt. And the reason there’s this real estate debt is because of the failure of the 19th century to achieve its main economic objective, which was to finance government not by taxing profits or wages, but by taxing land rent. And if you would have if all of the increase in land prices as a result of prosperity, population growth, and public spending, if all of this increase in prices were collect, were not given away to the landlords freely but were collected as the government, then this would this rent would not be available to pledged to the banks to pay interest. So simply taxing away land rent would prevent the financialization of land valuations, which is what most of the debt is in the United States. There are no need at all for this debt. Instead of paying an income tax by the wage earners and companies, they’d be paying a rent tax on the land, and this rent would not be used to pay interest.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Interesting. So you look like you have something you want to ask.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Well, it just seems to me like there’s two ways to look at the solution set to this. One is the post-collapse narrative. And one of them is something like what individuals right now can do in order to promote a better financial structure in the future. Like, are there things that people can actually do to take, for instance, not taking on debt? Is that a solution that people can actually contribute to this whole or is that an impossible wish?

 

Michael Hudson

No, not if you needed to break even. The break-even costs force you to go into debt. Then the economy is mal structured. A well-structured economy wouldn’t force you to go into debt. It wouldn’t force you to pay higher and higher debt service to the banks, to buy a home to live in, because it could be the same home that’s been there for a hundred years. If that’s going up in price, there’s no reason to have the banks earn money interest in their sleep by forcing you into debt to pay the land rent to the banks that can simply create the credit.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

So in that sense, all of our entire solution set is bounded in a top down view that we fundamentally have to restructure the system in order to actually get out of this hole.

 

Michael Hudson

There’s nothing that Adam Smith and Ricardo and John Stuart Mill and Marx and all of the classical free market was all about a free market as a market free of economic rent. And now it’s a market. It’s free for the wrong to is to take as much as they want without government regulation or taxation.

Steve Keen

And this is the point that looking back at the classical economics, first of all, it was a fighting the feudal system and arguing in favor of capitalists. So the feudal system was overwhelmingly landlords. You might be lord landlord, but you were still a landlord. So your wealth came out of land ownership, and they saw that it was unproductive, and they wanted to erect the wealth from the landlord class to the capitalists. And that gave you an anti-unearned income perspective.

The Classical school of Economics. And what’s happened with the neoclassical taking over? They’ve abolished that distinction. Everything is a marginal product. And therefore, the landlords, if you’re a wealthy landlord, you’ve got a large marginal product. It’s everything is a meritocracy. The classical school focused on the fact that wealth came out of ownership, not out of what you did with the neoclassical to abolish the whole idea that ownership has any role at all. Which is crazy because we’re talking about capitalism.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

I think that we should take a short break right here and refill coffee and maybe use the bathroom, because afterwards I want to get into a historical picture of how this happened, because what you guys are saying is that we went from feudalism to capitalism, and now we’re going from neoclassical economics, which took over from classical economics back into.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Financial feudalism.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Neo-feudalism And so I want to see if we can learn something by looking at that first transition and the one that’s happening now to see if we can accelerate the transition back out of it.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

There’s one more thing that I wanted to mention. We are organizing our very first conference, Mr. Con 2024, which we’re going to hold in Austin, Texas, April 7th and eighth of next year. We’re going to have two days of talks on astrophysics, cosmology, mythology, archeology, economics, consciousness with some of our favorite guests from the podcast. The link for that is down in the description. It’s also going to be up here in just a second. But if you have that weekend available and you are interested in joining us, please come over to our Eventbrite and purchase tickets now. If you cannot attend by coming in person, that’s totally fine. We also have tickets available for the live stream. So check that out right up here.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Guy I was just saying in the break to an associate that when I listen to other podcasts by non-economists and they talk about the financial crisis in America, let’s say just the sort of impoverishment of the average person, the idea is that the dichotomy is between socialism and the government stealing up people’s money or something. And capitalism, free market capitalism. And I think that that’s not the right dichotomy to be examining. I think we established that pretty early on. But why does that myth persist? Why is that something that most people on the street understand to be the dichotomy?

 

Anastasia Bendebury

And I imagine that it must be something of a historical artifact because it’s a reflection of the most recent economic conflict, which is, you know, Soviets versus Americans. Or, if you go even further back, it’s Karl Marx and the development of rising up to own the means of production. And so everybody just kind of fits it onto this pattern and just don’t go any deeper than that.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, there are many kinds of socialism, just too there are many kinds of capitalism and the idea of socialism. And prior to World War One was, as we said, the government was going to. Help industrial capitalism. And it was the industrialists that were pressing for socialism in the sense that they were pressing for government to provide as many public services as public utilities as they could in order to make the economy lower-priced and more competitive. And that’s what made industrial capitalism revolutionary. Getting rid of the landlord class was revolutionary.

Getting rid of the monopolies was revolutionary. And even turning money away from usury and just pure explosiveness into actually financing production was revolutionary. And all that seemed to be happening, especially in Germany, where you had a unity between government, the large banks, the Reichsbank, the military, and heavy industry. And that seemed to be the way to go in. And England’s financial policy would be to pay out profits as quickly as you could to the financial owners. It was a hit and run. But in Germany, the banks encouraged companies don’t pay out the profits the stockholders reinvested in your interest.

To grow so the economy can grow. We want to grow through equity, not through debt. Well, all of that changed in World War One. Is it true that the monitors were overthrown? But you also had a whole change in what socialism meant? And certainly, the Russian Revolution, as it turned into Stalinism, transformed the whole idea of socialism. And they thought of socialism as being intrusive and essentially either Stalinism or Naziism. Not as a byproduct of and evolution of industrial capitalism. And part of the problem was that the left wing, as it became solenoid, stopped talking about finance. And if you look at who are the people that read and pay attention to what Steve and I are saying, it’s sort of across the whole political spectrum.

It’s not left wing. If anything, it more right-wing, or is it more focused on finance than the left wing? And so the idea of economic reform no longer had a political vehicle for it. And beginning with Ricardo again in England. The critics of industrial capital said, Well, we’re not going to be able to get rid of the landlords until we democratize politics. We want to get rid of the House of Lords being able to dominate British policy, and we have to clean up the rotten boroughs.

We have to democratize that parliament. And all of this came to an explosive head in 1909 to 10 when the House of Commons actually passed a land tax revenue bill, and the House of Lords vetoed it. And that was a crisis. And the result was that the House of Lords could never again block a revenue bill. So the capitalist sector was all in favor of democracy. But, needless to say, the financial sector was all against democracy. The financial sector was, let’s put it plainly, fascist.

The financial sector did not want democracy unless it could manipulate the voters and confuse them into not understanding their class consciousness. And so you had a whole shift in how people thought about the economy—how they thought about what is capitalism and what is socialism. And the result is that the financial view of socialism is somehow high taxes on everybody and progressive taxation that would really hurt the poor more than the progressive people. All of that went by the wayside. Well, in 1913, the United States finished a whole fight with the Supreme Court. Are you allowed to actually tax wealth and tax income?

Well, finally, the Supreme Court let there be an income tax, but only 1% of Americans had to pay an income tax. And this 1% were Americans. The rich who made almost all their money through rents and finance rent seekers. Well, all of that changed when there was a counter-revolution and economic theory saying a progressive income’s bad. You want a flat tax today. The richer you are, the lower your tax bracket, the lower income you have, the more you pay in taxes and various fees. So you’ve had a failure of the population to understand what Steve and I are talking about. That’s why we’re on your show, not. Oh, oh, on…

 

Steve Keen

NBC. Yeah, well, it goes back further than that. And I think it was actually extended, but it’s actually a human characteristic as well, because if you read Doc, they very, very original neoclassical you have to read. Augustine Curnoe was a French mathematician around the turn of the 1800s. And Jean-Baptiste say, who was an economist and a libertarian in the 1820s, and they put across the idea of capitalism being utility, maximizing wealth, and maximizing systems. And it operated best when there was perfect competition, no monopolies in the sense of large companies, and they completely ignored the issue of land ownership and the issues we’re talking about the rent-seeking side.

And what you got was with what became neoclassical economics was largely attraction to Marx because Marx took the classical school of economic thought and then turned that not as a criticism of feudalism and support of capitalism, the criticism of capitalism and support of socialism. Marx was born to socialism, was what we call democratic socialism today now. Education for the workers, health care, etc., etc. But the vision that the Che put forward was of capitalism, free market capitalism as a utility-maximizing system.

And it gave me this vision of a world where there was no control and no power. So everything worked out fairly, and everybody got what they deserve for meritocracy. And humans, I think, have got to, and we see this in religions like Scientology and Catholicism and all the other religions around the world. We have a vision of a perfect society, and we’re very good at sharing that with each other. And capitalism, the neo-classical theory puts across capitalism is a perfect system. And that is what lies behind the neoclassical zealotry, because they think they’re going to make the world a better place if only they can get rid of the government intervention, get rid of trade unions, let the market decide, blah, blah, blah.

And one of my favorite experiences that ever was I set up and they I farcical economists who didn’t always being set up but it was I got to talk to a bunch of unionists and management in the food industry back in Australia. This is back when I worked in part of the government called the Accord, which was supposed to get unions and management to get together to cooperate.

Anyway, this guy came along, and he was the person who worked out what’s called the effective rate of protection. And it was strictly neoclassical or organized, socially workable. Called the Industries Assistance Commission, the nickname of which amongst both the manufacturers and the workers was the Industries Assassination Commission. They were trying to abolish tariffs, abolish controls, etc., etc. And this guy got blasted by both sides.

He had no idea was going to get shot, but he did. And I sat down with him after feeling sorry for him because he was, you know, nobody else was talking to him, and he’s sitting away and having a drink. And he finally says to me and I and I quote, Look, you’re an economist. Help me convert those people. It’s your religion, and they don’t realize it’s a religion and anything which contradicts that religion. They don’t look at they walk away from. So on a central part of the religion is the idea that cost of supply arises because of what they call rising marginal costs.

It costs more to produce a traditional unit of output, and that’s driven what they call diminishing marginal productivity, which is that each additional worker is assumed to be as productive as the previous worker. But because you’ve got a crowded factory, effectively they produce less output as more workers are added. So productivity per worker falls, cost per worker rises. Rising supply curve. When they go and research that, they find that every last bloody firm they interview virtually says that doesn’t apply to us. We’ve got constant or falling marginal costs.

We design factories are the most efficient at full capacity. And that’s what said dozens of surveys have been done. Every last one is found. At least 89% are normal. In 95% of firms report constant or falling marginal cost. Now, what that means is the whole theory of welfare that’s part of the model for it breaks down. So one of them made a big mistake. In a neoclassical economists called Alan Blinder made the mistake of doing a survey to ask manufacturers what they call structural work.

Got this answer, and literally, and I quote from his book, described as overwhelmingly bad news brackets for economic theory. It was such bad news that his textbook doesn’t even report his own research to his students. It continues with the myth. So this is what the behavior is, not a behavior of science, is behavior, religion, and anything which doesn’t fit the religion. You either don’t look at it in the first place. What he rejected, if you actually discover it and that comes back to that. What is a religion? It’s a way of saying this is the way to the promised land. So they say capitalism is the route to the promised land, and that’s why they fuck up the bloody thing, because there’s no relation whatsoever to the real world.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

And so, as a very…

 

Michael Hudson

Heavily subsidized religion and the most of the subsidy…

 

Steve Keen

Why, You’re on a bull.

 

Michael Hudson

Yes. Go to business schools, and the University of Chicago are founded by the Rockefellers to justify essentially his oil rent as sort of the leader in it is, quite frankly, a fascist university. That was where the Pinochet fascism came from. In Chile? It was from the Chicago school. That’s their doctrine, as is fascism.

 

Steve Keen

What they don’t know it is that they believe that they know what they have.

 

Michael Hudson

I want to tell. Let me tell you.

 

Steve Keen

Okay.

 

Michael Hudson

You weren’t there. I went to the high school when I was in high school and grade. There are the social science teacher, Curtis Edgett, had a big sign over the bulletin board. I better not say it, but it was pretty. Those of us who graduated from the high school and went on to college found when we got our FBI records that our professors normally turned in reports on us to the FBI about what we said in class all the time.

I mean, the result is that all this money going to the University of Chicago, Berkeley, and others they become they’ve taken over the editorship of all of the main economic journals. So and if you are a graduate in the United States, an economic graduate, whether you’re hired or not by a university, depends on whether how many articles you’ve had in the prestigious economic journals.

And needless to say, you have to have the party line, or, as Steve says, religion. I think a party line is better in order to get published there. So where I taught and most of modern monetary theory was taught at the University of Missouri at Kansas City, our graduates had great difficulty talking about money and debt and getting it published. They’d all get rejections. And as a result of having to publish only in the left wing journals, they had great difficulty getting hired by prestigious universities. So it’s a very well-subsidized junk economics, basically.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

And is the subsidy done in service of maintaining financial capitalism? Like what?

 

Michael Hudson

Amazingly enough, yes, of course it is there. But they’re going to they want to popularize something that says that they are productive, not unproductive. That’s the great myth, that the parasites are productive. They’re the parasites. Take over the body.

 

Steve Keen

No, I’m. From a broader experience, like not the mainstream university, like University of Chicago is absolutely top of the neoclassical pecking order. So I went to places like Sydney, New South Wales, western Sydney, Kingston, and so on in the UK, and you still get people who have got nowhere near this gravy train and nowhere near having political influence of paying working for the state, because often working in state-run universities and they start this religion, they actually believe it, and that’s why they’re so fucking dangerous other than the French, because if you have somebody who’s paid to believe it, so it’s all they helping out oil, blah, blah, blah, you can pay them a bit more money or that they’ve got to be at least partial.

They’ve got to have some sort of, you know, internal conflict out of the supporting a libertarian arguments and knowing they’re supporting multinational wealth and so on. But these people believe it, and they’re not even getting rewarded for it. So that’s why I say I see religion as more appropriate analogy, because you have true believers who are in poverty because of what they believe, but then they push out this myth of a libertarian meritocratic system, and that myth persists partly because of money at the top, but also because many people believe it. And humans in general, I think, are seduced by the idea of a vision of a perfect society.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, I think Wall Street is not as bad as the universities in Wall Street. They didn’t care what my politics were. They knew what my politics were. All they cared was whether I was right or wrong. And I did very well on Wall Street. But in academia, they didn’t care about whether I was right or wrong. All they cared about was what I believed. And they thought that be Certainly at the New School, which was a left-wing university under Bob Brunner. Well, it was a Stalinist university. They thought that because I came from Wall Street, I had to be a left winger.

Hull Brunner said, Look, if you’re talking about finance, you’re a right winger. And I wanted to cancel debt. And he said that would just discredit the entire left to account, talk about the need to cancel debt. And he he also attacked me for writing for Catholic publications and for having the Catholic Church popularize my ideas as part of the land reform issue. So I found that the universities, especially the left-wing universities, were the most hard-line right-wing religious people on Wall Street. And they welcomed my ideas because, Stephen, I have the right ideas. That’s why most of our support comes from the financial sector. They know what’s happening.

Steve Keen

It’s ironic, but true. Yeah.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

So if the financial sector sort of, well, you know, if the financial sector is…

 

Steve Keen

Supporting our policies, they support our analysis.

 

Michael Hudson

Yes.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

I see. Okay.

 

Michael Hudson

Internal use only?

 

Steve Keen

Like, for example, I’m looking at my analysis now of credit and unemployment, and people that followed my work developed what I call the credit accelerated or explained the rise and fall of asset prices and did very well out of speculating on the basis of that. I don’t have the money to speculate, but, you know, I know people have made a large amount of money out of following the idea that Michael has on other people who are not all non-Orthodox thinkers because we’re actually identifying what’s going to cause a big change in the market next. Whereas the Neo-Classical Church, there’s nonsense of the efficient markets hypothesis. And you all know Warren Buffet. Obviously, Buffet was being criticized when he was doing his degree and saying, look, there’s no profit to be made. The market is efficient; instead of that’s true, I’m going to be broke. Oh, we ain’t broke.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

So what is inside of the finance? If the people in the inside of the financial sector realize that things are broken? What are the decisions that they are attempting to make in order to fix it? Or is the dream?

 

Michael Hudson

To fix their idea of fixing it is to make as much money as they can. They want to fix it by increasing the stock prices on which their bonuses are fed. They want to fix it by using profits to pay out dividends and for stock buybacks, not to invest. They want to fix it by making more money for themselves. That’s their idea, acting rationally.

 

Steve Keen

So we’re trying to say, look, this and this is why the system fucks up. Let’s do something to fix it. And they say, This is what the system fucks up. Let’s ride the wave. So you do get some people in finance. I mean, Nick Hanauer, for example, is somebody who is a socially minded billionaire, and he will be putting forward ideas about how we have to do. His next book is on the on this topic of reforming a system.

I don’t know if you go as far as actually agreeing with the wealth confiscation or you going to modern debt jubilee; maybe he would with a modern Dutch overlay. But in general, people in finance are looking for an advantage. And if you’re following a theory which is not delusional, then you’re going to have an advantage. And Warren Buffett was the classic one of following a non-delusional theory. The efficient market hypothesis said you can’t find a badly priced company. And he said, You’ve got to be kidding. So that’s how he made his money.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, Steve used the word reform. And the question is it is reform enough, or do you need a revolution? Reform is simply fixing an existing structure to make it stronger. A revolution is to change the structure. And we’ve reached a point at which, in order to save the economy, save the environment, save the world’s military situation, you need really a revolution. And I think Marx said the end of capitalism will not be a pretty sight on one occasion. And in a way, the runt. It’s very funny.

The people who are the debtors and the wage earners are not going to lead a revolution violently. Violence. Ever since Greece and Rome all the way to modern times, violence is always used by the Free lunchers by the rontiers, by the takers to protect their predatory power is not by the victims. Violence is by the victimizers, unfortunately. And so you need this forces of revolution.

As you saw in Latin America, You had the revolutions have been sponsored by the United States. They’ve all been from the right wing, from the pro-financial, neo feudal or outright the fascist Pinochet to Chicago sector. You had the one country that’s immune, mostly of China, that had its own revolution in order to make all of this possible.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Well, prior to the fascist revolution, there was something of a democratic revolution in Chile, from what I understand, right? They had some sort of democratic election. This didn’t go over well. The redistribution of land didn’t go over well.

 

Michael Hudson

Right?

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Yeah, particularly with the foreign aid.

 

Michael Hudson

Kissinger said Yeah, just because they vote wrong doesn’t mean that we should follow them. When you use the word democracy, Democracy is a euphemism for oligarchy. We’re not in a democracy. We’re in an oligarchy. And if you don’t realize that, then you don’t understand who’s making the decisions of power and what governments are doing to protect oligarchic power against other people. And Aristotle, in his book on constitutions, said many constitutions claim to be democratic, but they’re really oligarchic. And that’s as much the case today as it was in his day.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Okay. So one of the problems that I see with debt cancellation is we had this very active debate about the canceling of student deaths over the course of the last few years. Definitely, people are still talking about it. And on some level, I am viscerally pro-the cancellation of student debt. On the other hand, what I see happening is you have the massive increase in the cost of education that’s going to the administrations and not towards professors and students like there was. I looked at this the other day. I think that Harvard has a 1:1 ratio almost of students to administrators. And so it feels like what you do in that case by canceling student debt is, yes, you relieve the individual, but you have passed. An approving judgment on the structure of the universities that allows you to maintain this kind of. But I mean.

Okay, let me see if I can lay out the way that you have this. So if you have a student that pays money to a university where most of the money is going to the administrators and they’ve taken the money out as a loan and they don’t end up paying back the loan, but the loan is forgiven. The university has made a large profit. And there is nothing that prevents the university from continuing to extract wealth from the financial sector. By getting these students to take these massive loans. The students get their loans eventually forgiven, but the system continuously ratchets up costs.

 

Steve Keen

The system began by making students borrow money to do education and experiences from the very beginning, to where I literally caused a bit of a dispute in the Vice-Chancellors office when I decided to resign from Kingston University. This huge growth in administrators is all the product of turning universities into profit centers because when the universities were government-funded, this is, I’m talking in Australia’s case, now government-funded.

They did have private fees initially. So if you didn’t get in through competitive means, you could buy your way in. But most of the people got that through competitive matches. And then, in 75, I began university, not in 71. In 73 we had a progressive Labor government come in which abolished student fees, and that meant you went to university if you got a good enough mark. That was the only interesting 80 was good school results, and at that point, the ratio of administrators to staff would have been 1 to 2, or 12333 academic staff for every administrator, and the administrators were there to do the administrative work for the academics.

So the hierarchy was definitely, you know, academics above administrators below. When we got this push to commercialize universities again, the administrators became marketers. They ended up on top there telling you what to do. I had this enormous growth in a ship structure of what our great old friend David Graber called Bullshit Jobs, whose whole role was to try to market the university. And then what they did knock out the bloody vice chancellor. There’s just a damned clock. And you know, you see all the public relations for the university.

It wasn’t about the innovative academic staff; it was what a great Vice-Chancellor we had. So this huge hierarchy of bullshit jobs, the support the Vice-Chancellor developed out of commercializing it, and they’re also competing the day they start. A University of Western Sydney starts a department in Saskatchewan to try to compete for the Saskatchewan market, and they all try to get extra market share. It’s ludicrous, and what is meant is far more of the money and administer university.

This does go to administration and marketing than actually goes to research and teaching. And I’ve lived through it has been a bloody nightmare. And that’s why I was glad to leave the university sector in 2018. And I’ve done far more academic work since I left than I ever managed when I was there, because I got rid of all the stupid form-filling and ludicrous reports to bureaucrats. You haven’t got a fucking clue. Pardon me? I’m becoming really Australian talking about this. I haven’t got a clue what an academic actually does, and got in the way of us doing the work that we all became academics to try to do in the first place. So the whole bureaucratization and overloading of universities has been a product of commercializing them, believing the profit motive would work better for managing universities.

In fact, it’s corrupting that extremely badly, even to the point where I have had students say, Look, I’ve paid for my degree, like I’ve been shopping at Kmart and bought something, and I think I can walk out the door because I paid the bill. Sorry, you’re not bright enough. You deserve to fail. You can’t tell. You’ve got to pass you to get your studies. There’s enough idiots already, you know. But that’s if you abolish student fees and abolish private funding, abolish the students, you don’t treat the student like a consumer. The student’s a student that had a lot. And so they’ve got to compete well enough to get in; if they don’t do well enough, so they fail.

You know, I’m quite a libertarian in most of my attitude, but if you’re not smart enough, you don’t get the exams on your failure. Repeat, you can’t do that to them these days. So the whole if you got rid of the whole superstructure of training, image of market and private institutions, you’d reduce the cost structure quite radically and you’d make it cheaper to educate, and you’d have academics. You’ve got time to be academics and think as well as changes well, rather than the shit we have those does.

 

Michael Hudson

Well. There’s a race to the bottom going on also that you have. How do you maximize your profit? You lower. The cost of production, how many? And instead of hiring full-time teachers in the United States at, let’s say, 60,000 a year, you can hire part-time teachers at $2,500 a year for your course. And so you’ve had pushing them way down. There was a protest. I live in New York City, and I have friends who are professors at NYU, and they had the professors who were complaining that no new professors were being hired. They were all part-timers. And you’re having graduate students do the teaching and no higher hires. And the there are more and more deans, and some deans and bureaucrats, as Steve pointed out, being appointed. And what is the job of a dean? It’s to lower the price of the people working for you, the lower the cost of teaching, and giving the the income you save to yourself.

So you make money by lowering the wages that are paid to the other people. So the professors have been downsized, basically. And. A premium is put on inexperienced, literally the race to the bottom. But that’s not really the main cost. The main what made China so great for thousands of years was Confucianism. The idea that everybody was going to take exams and you would have the best people.

Basically, ending up as the administrators if you make, if you limit university registration to the rich and say if you don’t inherit your wealth, you’re going to have to go into a lifetime of debt in order to get an education. And if you do not inherit enough money from your parents to pay, then you’re not going to be able to buy a house. When you graduate, you’re not going to be able to start a family because no bank will lend you money because your income over and above basic consumption goes to pay the university. Sorry, you can’t afford a house. That’s the result of not writing down student debt and of teaching, treating education not as a public utility, not as a human right, but as a profit center. That’s the result.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

And that’s exactly what I am pointing to. Which is like…

 

Steve Keen

Saying you don’t abolish the debt.

 

Michael Hudson

You don’t run in the first place.

 

Steve Keen

You abolish the debt. You get the whole commercialization. You get rid of the administrative layer, and you drastically reduce the cost. And the state pays for education.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

But If you abolish the debt after, because the students pay in the moment, the universities have already gotten that money. And so if you abolish the debt without a simultaneous shift in the way that the universities do business, then the universities are not suffering the ill effects of that debt abolishment because if…

 

Michael Hudson

No, they’ve already got paid. This debt is owed to the government. It doesn’t cost the government a penny to cancel the debt. It just is not going to collect the debt from the people. But a windfall benefit.

 

Steve Keen

But we’re definitely in favor of completely changing the university system as well. It’s a nightmare. I about when I did a study back on the 90s, late 80s early 90s, and when I took it on I took I suffered a substantial pay drop, but I didn’t regard myself as putting myself in poverty for future. Now the pay the students in most universities certainly American university tend to be better actually on this front better pay rates. But the pay rates are so bad that I’ve ended up telling my students, in later years, don’t get a job at the university, learn how to make coffee, become a barista, work 9 to 5. If they force work later than five, I’ll pay you time and a half.

When you get home, you’ll have plenty of energy to do the research you would have done if you had time as an academic. But instead, all the academics are working two and three positions to basically, you know, it should be over paper in front of a blackboard. Terrible situation, terribly insecure. It’s an awful lot of style. And that means what? You then saying you’re only an idiot would work at a university, and that ends up with a dumb population. Oh, we want to get back to the stage of education, as Michael said, is a Confucian thing. It’s the highest. It’s the exact most exalted role. You get your best people in there, and you get them. give them time to think, and we haven’t done it. We’re screwing up a capacity to think, and we’re supposed to be, you know, an intelligent species.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, I think that’s a vocabulary problem here. You’re using the word university. What you really mean as a real estate company that holds classes in some of its real estate in order to get tax exemption on all of its other real estate. The largest real estate investors are owners in New York, Columbia University, and New York University. They came to them. Giving an education is just part of the annoying overhead. They’re into making real estate gains and increasing their endowment. That’s so we really shouldn’t think of them as teaching at all. They’re real estate companies with a tax exemption.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

But even so, Columbia and NYU private universities. And so this real estate company model for them makes a lot of sense. But I’m thinking about even the University of California system, which is a public system. And, you know, I was just looking at it in the 1980s. I think tuition was $700 for a semester, and now I think it’s over 20,000.

 

Michael Hudson

Thank you, Ronald Reagan.

 

Steve Keen

And that’s all the cost. Gross By turning into privately run organizations. And this this myth we’re talking about earlier, the neoclassical. Believe everything is done better privately, you know, lower costs, more efficient, blah, blah, blah. In fact, what happens is you have university that used to be happy with their own intake. You know, the University of Los Angeles wasn’t going to get students from San Diego. Then you put them into commercial. They’re all competing for market share. So they start marketing a huge increase in marketing costs.

They have all these bureaucrats who are now involved in packaging, you know, sales materials at the universities. An enormous distribution costs. All that stuff doesn’t exist when you don’t have private competition, and you’re far better off having publicly funded, well, publicly funded universities than private ones. A few private make it makes sense in somewhat in some areas, but to privatize the entire system ends up in a disaster. And that’s what we’ve got now. And I’ve lived the experience of going from the days when it was state-controlled and state-funded, and you had to get good results to get in, and no money was paid. Now a fortune is paid and the whole of effort, everything is about getting more students in and marketing, and that dominates everything, including the tuition.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, let’s talk about why there are public universities in America to begin with. They were created after World War, after the Civil War, as a result of the Republicans protectionists, the industrialists coming to power. And the and I wrote a whole book about this. Americans protectionists take off the Republicans fruit, and the industrial capitalists who they represented had a problem. People who went to the prestige private universities. Harvard was considered to be the worst. But there were other bad ones.

Yale and all of the Ivy League universities basically all taught British free trade. You in theory, the you know, the private universities in America until the civil war were basically for training members of the clergy, and their economic course was taught in the fourth year, the year senior year of college. And it was more; it was called moral philosophy. And this was all free trade. It was all British free trade theory. And the Republicans came in and the business interests and said, how are we going to get people educated? And reality economics, the fact that free trade benefits the dominant country and prevents countries like us from catching up, Well, we’re going to create state universities. And what we’re going to do, we’re going to give every state a land grant, and the land grant is going to enable them to fund courses for the public at large. And this is going to be where reality economics is taught instead of the British free trade right-wing theory. And that you had, in addition to the state universities, you had the first business schools that were funded and the business schools were all staffed by Americans who had studied in Germany and came back, as the Social Democrats are outlined, social outright socialists, and the first economics professor in the United States at the first business school was Simon Peyton at the Wharton School of Economics at the University of Pennsylvania, who developed the whole idea of public infrastructure as a fourth factor of production, but a factor of production that didn’t seek profits or rents but sought to lower the price for the economy as a whole.

It was the business schools and the state colleges that taught so essentially how industrial capitalism would evolve into a mixed economy, a quasi-socialist economy, to benefit capital formation. And all of this, again, was changed in modern times. Somehow, the universities have been financialized and taken over, and become part of the the race to the bottom. And as a result, you had a stratification of the American economy. If you don’t inherit a wealth from your family, you have a lifetime of debt. And that is dividing the economy into two classes, the debtor class and the inheritance class. And is that really what you want the university system to produce a class conflict?

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Yeah, definitely. I mean, that’s a huge problem. I see it in the small we teach, so we actually we’re living this; we’re teaching at a university. So we teach at Southern Oregon University, which is about an hour away. And so I was teaching astrophysics and cosmology and teaching microbiology labs. And it’s really interesting because there’s some students that are first generation who are working full time, going to school full time, and they have this very, very clear vision for what their path is going to look like.

Like, there’s one girl in one of my classes. She’s the oldest of four. She is, and her siblings are basically first generation born in the country. And she works full-time at a coffee shop and wants to be a plastic surgeon. And she just she has this arc laid out for herself, and she’s very, very competent. And then there’s other students who are clearly they’ve been admitted to a for-profit system that doesn’t really care if they succeed or they don’t succeed because they don’t come to class, they don’t do the work, and they’re being charged for it.

They’ve probably taken a loan to arrive there, and there’s no mechanism by which the university takes it upon itself to say, Hey, you need to stop paying us because this is extortionist and immoral and just continues to collect from students that probably shouldn’t be there, like they should take a couple of years figured out and come back. And it’s really heartbreaking because it just seems like a place that is meant to be the source of foundational knowledge and wisdom for the society has been converted to yet another place of financialization, profits. And these interests drive everybody into the ground.  

Steve Keen

And you’re talking about that going…

 

Steve Keen

That is such a dangerous thing to do. But what’s the most important foundational thing of a civilized society is education.

 

Michael Hudson

But you’re talking about education and something real. The fact is, if you and I were in a university, we couldn’t fit what we’re talking about into the curriculum. Right?

 

Steve Keen

I had to make my own break. I’m like, I succeeded. I went up as I went down, like I started off o the top university in Australia, where I led a student revolt against economic teaching in 1973. I then used the second one, where I got my pay, I’d say, until I sacked all the tutors. When there was a government decision in favor of employee employment permanency, they sacked all the tutors to get rid of having to give them permanent straight. And then I moved to a second-rate university of Western Sydney, where all the rebels ended up the mainly rebels. And so we had a progressive department there, and then Kingston. So I’ve been succeeding, going up for professorial scale, while the university I’ve been teaching, I have been going down, but all the top universities is taken over by neo classical they dropped.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

That’s actually one of the really wonderful benefits of teaching out of the university that nobody knows anything about is that there isn’t a ton of oversight in terms of people telling me what I have to talk about in class. I actually sometimes sit in knock, and I’m like, I’m kind of like, Wow, this is amazing that I can sit here and talk about some of these subjects that I would never get away with. You know, back in New York, like at Columbia, where we were out for grad school, I just could, you know, it would have been this very structured curriculum that fit into the wider political landscape and so forth. And so that’s where you got to ask about, you know, if you can afford to do teaching as a public service as opposed to a career, then it’s quite nice for.

 

Steve Keen

So much about a lifestyle. Yeah, sure.

 

Michael Hudson

And you’re talking about the core curriculum. And what I meant you can’t fit what Steve and I are talking about into the core curriculum. Like at the New School, I wanted to teach about money in banking, and they really didn’t want that. It was the left wingers. It was Howard Bronner who didn’t want money in banking. They said that I was a critic of banking, not supporting it. And again, he didn’t want me to talk about debt. So the core curriculum Is now even worse? Now, as I said, there’s no history of economic thought in the core curriculum. There’s no economic history in the curriculum.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

You know, history in the sciences either, which is really disturbing.

 

Michael Hudson

And I make history.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Yeah. Or lack of history. I feel like that’s a huge problem in innovation, too, is that people don’t have time to go back and study in the sciences, how people are arrived at the various ideas that are popular, and how much debate really persisted throughout the last few centuries. Right. A lot of the things people take for granted—you know, the equations they learned, they were fought tooth and nail over, and there’s still a lot of wiggle room that remains in some of those fundamental sciences. But no one would ever have the time to go back and check it out. Now, that’s a bit tragic.

 

Steve Keen

Yep. That’s wrong. It’s worse than economics in that sense. I mean, I remember being at the University of New South Wales in 1987—88, I think it was. And the. I think historians were so sick of how they were being treated by the economic staff that because what happened was they were forever having, of course, chopped off and replaced by caution, econometrics, some particular application of econometrics. So they made an arrangement to move to the faculty. And there was I remember the meeting quite vividly. They were pleading to be allowed to leave to go to the arts faculty, and the economics would not let them do that.

They didn’t want to trumpet called economics in the arts. Faculty were offended by it. And of course, ultimately, they shot down the Economic History Unit by association, economic, I should say, history, economic, social and history and Marxian economics. And they were both also shut down. So all the contemplative stuff disappeared. And the irony is now that neoclassical economists like, and I’m thinking specifically, people I know at Cambridge University have no idea even if their own history, let alone the history of the institution they read, let alone the history of the discipline. And that ignorance is where a huge amount of stupidity comes from in how economics develops further.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, the irony there is that it’s the orthodox economics that should be in the arts. Faculty is part of the science fiction of the little guy.

 

Steve Keen

No, no, no. We’re like religion. Religion.

 

Michael Hudson

Okay.

 

Steve Keen

I mean, I’ve got. I’ve got to get a break. Did you enjoy that paper I sent you a couple of days ago? That was a great book, David Graber. Okay, look, I’ll give you an idea of what it’s like. Give me a second. I’m going to find something on fiction. I’ll read it out to you because in 2000, the Chinese of the millennia, the leading the most influential journal, the Quarterly Journal of Economics. That’s right.

Number one out of the University of Chicago. The number of economists around naturally tried to write a survey of where economics was and what’s been the progress in the last century, and what can happen. I get and a guy is actually a nice bloke. I met him ultimately called Atlas Air; he became the chief economic advisor to Bush. So he was chief, and I was the president during the financial crisis. And he wrote a paper called Economic Imperialism. And it wasn’t a criticism. U.S. economics should be imperialistic because it’s the only social science. Well, then, you know, pride cometh before the fall because the financial crisis occurred. And when I caught up with him in 2009, he said to me and it was private conversation, but he’s dead now, so I can repeat it. He said, I don’t know why they appointed made chief adviser. I’m a labor economist. I don’t know anything about macroeconomics. I’ll find that quote. This will give you an idea of the ideology and economics factual.

 

Michael Hudson

All you’re looking for. If modern economic mainstream was correct, civilization never could have taken off. Imagine if there would have been a Milton Friedman or Chicago boy a going back to Hammurabi, going back to the Bronze Age, and said, No, no, you can write it. You cannot cancel the debts because that’s disturbs things. You have to let everybody collect the debts. You’d have the whole country living in poverty, as the biblical prophets described. What would happen if you didn’t have the Mosaic Jubilee year of Debt camp?

 

Steve Keen

And again, as Michael’s the expert here, but a huge part of the struggles because we read about the great man of history, the Caesars versus this ptolemies and so on, it was all, you know, say’s there was trust me, a wrong him, but Caesar was in favor of repaying reducing the debt.

 

Michael Hudson

Yes.

 

Steve Keen

And he was knocked off by the anti the the Victorian class, whatever they call it up against the tax. They didn’t want to abolish the debt. So huge parts of the struggles throughout history have been debtors versus creditors, and societies work best when the identities of one.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, they feared he was canceling the debts. And in fact, the only debts that he canceled were the debts owed by the rich people. The financial sector is all for canceling the debts that it owes, but not the debts that are owed to it. And that was one of Caesar’s failings. And if you look at the there were a lot of Roman debt cancellations, canceling back taxes, and they were almost entirely it was the large landowners and the large creditors that benefited, not the indebted population that had already lost its land through debt foreclosure.

Anastasia Bendebury

So go ahead.

Steve Keen

Oh, can I read this thing? This will give you an idea of what economics is like, because we’re likely not to do economics. This is the nature of economic thinking. This is a 2000 paper called Economic Imperialism. Economics has been successful because, above all, economics is a science. The discipline emphasizes rational behavior maximization, trade-offs, and substitutions and insists on models that result in equilibrium. Economists are pushed further to inquire because they understand the concept of efficiency and inefficient equilibria. Beg for explanation.

I should just there may be gaps in the underlying models. That created them, etc., etc. That’s why I rewrote it at the end. And that’s the first; there’s actually two paragraphs like that. So the economics of being successful because, above all, economics is a cult. Its dominant sex emphasizes rational behavior maximization, trade-offs, and substitution. And it’s just a model that results in equilibrium, thus insulating itself from the developments of 20th-century sciences. Economists push further into relevance because they are obsessed with the concept of efficiency. Inefficient equilibrium begs for dynamic and evolutionary explanations. I suggest there may be gaps in the brain. Wiring of economists should not understand this, but this is the world we’ve lived in. Yeah, and they think they’re being unscientific, and their definition of science should make a real scientist pure models that result in equilibrium. Which century are you from? But that’s the mindset inside economics.

 

Michael Hudson

Yes, And the same in international trade theory. All of the trade the Nobel Prize to Samuelson is that trade theory makes everybody all the proportions equal between capital and labor, and it’s just the opposite. If you have free trade, you polarize the economy, which is what the Americans realized when they decided to have a protectionist policy. That is what made them get so rich between the Civil War and World War One. So you’re right. It’s an economy is inherently polarizing and disequilibrium. But you know what? Equilibrium. When an economics professor falls trips and falls on his face flat on the floor. That’s the equilibrium. You know, I mean, when society collapses, that’s equilibrium. You know, what is he going to bring me?

 

Steve Keen

Well, what it means is they haven’t got they haven’t been able to develop evolutionary thinking. They suppress it because, for an equilibrium, there’s no point evolving any further equilibrium, which they think is scientific, has locked them out from all the developments from Lorenzen and complex systems and Chaos theory, and so on. And that’s that’s why you will not get progress that locked themselves into a dead end. Incredibly complicated, not complex. Mathematics is what they do.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, that’s because if you talk about evolution, you’re talking about the economy as a system with feedback. And all of the mainstream economics is what they call partial equilibrium. You can have just change 1 or 2 variables, and the whole context remains unchanged. But any kind of evolution, any kind of a system, there’s feedback that continually trend self transforms the system. That’s why Marx wrote at the very beginning of capital: he wants to look at the laws of motion of capitalism. Well, economy says we don’t want an emotion. We don’t want anything to change. We’re in the ruling class right now, and we don’t want to change it. We don’t want to look at any law motion that’s going to reform and revolutionize society and take away what we’ve grabbed.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

I wonder. Okay.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Well, I wanted to pivot a little bit back. So I’m hearing I’m hearing revolution from Michael and collapse from Steve. And I want to be able to imagine what comes after that. Are these changes things that can be implemented at the constitutional level if there is a new state, say, that appears, or what sort of reconstruction ideas could go into a better state in the future?

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Like after the Mad Max period?

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Yeah, after the Mad Max.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Okay, we have Mad Max. What happens? Is somebody rises from the ashes and is like, Let’s write a new document?

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Well, let’s assume that neo-feudalistic financial capitalism is a dead end and an inevitably fails in whatever way that it does. What should we expect, you know, as the partners of a new constitution? Is this something that can be fixed at the outset?

 

Michael Hudson

Well, that’s what you’re having in the whole international economy. That’s what the BRICs Plus is all about. The world is polarizing between the garden and the jungle. You have the whole Shanghai Cooperation Organization, the whole China, Russia, the whole global majority is realizing that what they call dollarization isn’t simply not using the dollar. It’s creating a new kind of an alternative to the International Monetary Fund, an alternative to the World Bank, an entirely new system of international relations. Multipolarity is what they’re talking about. So you’re saying that you’re not seeing that, and the revolution is not occurring in the West. You have the counter-revolution here.

The revolution is now in Eurasia. That’s where the revolution is. And you’re going to see a China-type mixed economies are going to take off because that’s where the industrialization is. The trade, the research, the rising living standards. You’re going to have the Eurasia and the global South unify into exactly where industrial capitalism seemed to be going in the 19th century. And you’ll have the United States and Europe and the post-industrial society, meaning a left back into neo-feudalism. So until finally, you know, presumably the garden is going to decide to let the jungle in and to have the mixed economy that the classical economics has expected all along but which you’re only finding in Eurasia now. And they call it socialism.

 

Steve Keen

That’s the optimistic view. Because I’m working on climate change, and I’m reading what the climate scientists are talking about and reading what economists are bullshitting about. I expect a total breakdown of society. And it’ll be a question of which societies survive through their whole process. It’s not going to be like a global collapse, just like climate change is not going to be an instantaneous thing everywhere. It’s going to be something where some societies can cope and others don’t, depending on the challenges we face.

We’re already seeing, you know, absolutely crazy weather in the last three years, getting more crazy every year. You know, this month, October, last month, rather, was 1.8 degrees above pre-industrial average. We’re talking about staying below 1.5. We’ve had three months in a row. We’re above 1.5 quite substantially. And so, according to economists, that will have a trivial impact upon the economy, but also, according to economists and this is there’s a survey by … I don’t know who the heck.

I think there might be commercial researchers, Howard, and saw them as, while I did a survey on 2021, getting the consensus of economists on climate change, and they predicted that seven degrees of warming in two centuries time. A trajectory towards that. So seven degrees by 2020 would reduce global GDP by 20% compared to what it would have been in the absence of global warming. And that would mean that rather than being 21 times the size of today’s economy, it’ll only be 17 times. So the actual impact on the rate of economic growth was a reduction in the annual rate of economic growth of 0.02%, which is one fifth of the accuracy with which economists can currently measure real change in GDP over time.

So in other words, trivial the way the science papers and there’s a paper saying in 2021 I’ve got I’ll find it necessary on my computer, what level of temperature increase over the preexisting level caused the previous six mass extinctions? And the answer is 5.2 degrees. So a 5.2-degree increase in temperature over the previous level triggered the last six major mass extinctions, where 85% or more of species went extinct. So economists think you can go two degrees higher than that and have a small direction in the rate of growth of economic growth.

That’s how ignorant they are. But the trouble is, politicians don’t know just how ridiculous their work is. They think this is based on scientific research. They don’t read the scientists. They read the economists instead. And so we’re blindly walking into this catastrophe. That’s why we’ve done nothing about global warming. So what I expect is and you also got politicians are charged who are narcissists. They’re not chosen for their skills or their decision-making process. They’re idiots.

So they’re going to make the wrong decisions anyway in response to all this. So I just see a period of massive chaos. Maybe a couple of societies will have a chance of surviving. China is one, though. China has a problem in that it doesn’t produce all its own food, which is a major issue. As we know, because you can’t feed your population, you can’t hold it together. So there’s a minority of countries which are food self-sufficient right now, major exporters, including America, as it happens. But I can’t see America holding together. So the small ones that don’t have America’s weapons problem might have a chance of survival. And then it’s a question of: What do we do to respond? Will there be massive geoengineering attempts, given what productive capacity we have in that situation? I think there will be, I think to save chaos and temperature levels. If you actually get successful geoengineering.

So I say a horrific if we’re lucky, 50 years, we’re unlucky. 500. And out of that, you get a civilization that develops. But my fear there is we’re going to get a civilization that is anti-technology. And you’d end up with a religious, you know, and seeing technology as the cause of the chaos we’re about to go through. When, in my opinion and from my reading of the literature, the blame lies with the economists who encouraged us to continue growing when the engineers and the engineers broke limits to growth. Not hippies.

Engineers 50 years ago were saying we have to take up, we have to reduce our rate of growth, we have to stabilize population, have to stabilize our energy. What would follow the engineers? We wouldn’t be in the situation we’re in, but the engineers will most likely get the blame, and you’ll likely get an anti-technical society coming out of that. So I think we’re going to be back wearing, you know, men wearing dresses telling us what to do. And maybe there might be have a lucky day. I might have a 500 million people listening to them because the other 7.5 billion aren’t going to make it.

 

Michael Hudson

All the economists are really just hired guns to promote this. I was working at the Hudson Institute in the 1970s, and one of the programs we had was a national security study of global warming that was run by the CIA. The CIA expected everything that you’ve talked about, Steve. And they said, and this is America’s interest because we’re a food surplus country, and this will a global warming will wreck the rest of the world and increase our power. We’re all for it.

We’re going to put all of our strength behind the oil industry. And one of the byproducts of that was Erda. The Energy Research Development Organization said we’ve got to develop the tar sands in Canada. That’s the most polluting source of energy in the world. We’ve got to speed up global warming to speed up America’s dominance. This is what the CIA was believing and telling, and hiring economists to produce. They didn’t circulate my study or the, you know, the internal studies for national security, but they hired your economists to be the public relations people for all of this. So they knew it. And it was the United States that was pushing the idea of global warming, thinking it will benefit because of its control of the oil industry.

 

Steve Keen

Yeah. I’m sure that was being part of it. But economists play their own role. Nordhaus destroyed the industry.

 

Michael Hudson

They played a role.

 

Steve Keen

The standing. But you did have some people in the oil industry who were saying this is going to be catastrophic over the long term. But in terms of the capacity, Americans assert themselves in the foot. I’m never going to argue against.

 

Michael Hudson

Okay.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

There’s been an interesting push for special economic zones, where people are seeing that this is starting to collapse. And I think that they’re looking to history, and they’re saying, okay, well, one of the greatest vessels for change is the ability to go to a place where rules have not been set up yet, where things are not yet calcified into the old systems, and to begin again. And so I know people that are part of various projects. Oftentimes, they’re libertarian projects.

I know that Peter Thiel is in the background talking about, you know, like sea civilizations. And that, to me, feels like an on one hand, I think it’s destined to fail. But on the other hand, I also look at it as being the only possible way to start to cede something that can run and grow in parallel to the systems that we have. Because if you’re right, and if it does, just shake itself apart. That’s the worst possible outcome. Like if you always are always use the same example.

If you build a new bridge like there was, the Bay Bridge in San Francisco needs to be rebuilt. They didn’t wait for the bridge to fall and then build a different bridge. They built the new span directly next to it. And when the span was built and tested, they redirected traffic to it and took apart the old one. And so are special economic zones a possible way to rebuild the span while the other one is busy collapsing? Or is that just a pipe?

 

Michael Hudson

Not now.

 

Steve Keen

You need the climate supports is a dangerous civilization, and we’re generating one that doesn’t support a sedentary civilization. This is not like London at the moment. It didn’t have as much damage that they thought it would cause, but the storm around was actually a Category three cyclone went through London. Now, they’re lucky about the way that the storm. Well, the damage was distributed. London didn’t get totally destroyed or anything like that.

It’s fairly minor, apparently, and landing pretty damn dramatic on the coast of Brittany. But if those things those the storm comes through like that, you know, if you happen to be in the region where you’re trying to build your bridge and then you get a cyclone like that or a period of high temperature that destroys the grain or hailstones that destroy your greenhouse, etc., etc., you’re going to have to persuade for on a an incredible industrial scale to be in any sense immune to that. And you’re going to need people. You’re going to need skilled people who are going to be willing to work for you when the fact that you have money is no longer relevant. So to me, you know, it only do it if you have a real egalitarian, survivalist society. And what I’ve been saying so far isn’t egalitarian.

Michael Hudson

All ideological moves have been made in economic collapse. It’s a lot quicker to make a fortune in economic collapse than in a non-economic collapse. And I can guarantee you, there are a lot of financial speculators looking at what is written and saying, okay, there’s going to be a crisis, environmental crisis. How can we make money off this?

 

Steve Keen

And they’re not going to happen. But they’re just too crazy. Too crazy.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

I wonder if you have been exposed at all to what’s called the dumber optimist community.

 

Steve Keen

No, I was brought up. I know quite a few communities in the area. So tell me about them are optimists.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

And optimists are basically people that I would bet agree with you largely on the course of human events in the way that the industrial system is going to collapse. And in the shadow of the collapsing Megalodon, they’re basically scavenging parts of it in order to be able to build family- and community-based systems that are going to be able to weather the collapse and be sufficiently robust to operate in the absence of money, like you say, because you’re exactly right. If money disappears, the thing that you need is an ideological commitment to the system that you’re building. And it seems like this is the time for the emergence of these kinds of groups, because lots of people are realizing that capitalism can’t keep going the way that it’s going.

I think everybody’s very pessimistic about reform. And so the only possible alternative is to build these systems. And a lot of them are farm-based. A lot of them are buying properties in, you know, Ecuador and Costa Rica and in places where they’re going to be largely protected against giant temperature increases because, from everything that we’ve learned in talking to climate scientists, the greatest temperature increases are going to happen away from the equator. So the equator is going to stay about the same. And so if you move to the tropics, then the impacts will be significantly less. And a lot of these people are moving to Central America.

There’s also the massive changes in climate zones that might happen, like 5000 years ago, the Sahara was a green paradise. And so if you have climate change and Europe becomes inhospitable, covered with an ice sheet, it might be that Northern Africa suddenly becomes the paradise in the garden. And so you do have to see a massive shift of people. But it’s not that this species goes extinct; and the people who will flourish in the condition. By necessity, will have to be the ones that embrace technology. Right. Because how could you not embrace technology and survive that?

 

Steve Keen

Is the problem we have scale? So, look, I agree that is more likely to be a survivable system, but it has to be what Nate Hagens ? I’m pleasure you know Nate Hagens calls a great simplification because you’re not going to have computer chips in that world. You may have to go back to resistors and try to have valve-based computers, something you can manufacture on a small scale, because the extent to which we have the scale of manufacturing is beyond most people’s comprehension today.

You know, the one company that makes the machines that make the chips, the advanced chips, which is a Dutch company, I think, was $450 million per machine. And there’s only one company making it. So they won’t have a market to make those machines. If you’re down to a population of, you know, scattered populations of between 500,000 and 50 million surviving in wood plastic around the equator, ironically, I think you’re quite right about that. So they’re going to have to be technological, but it’s going to have to be a bit like, if you know, the old Kiva. It’s survival technology. It’s not large-scale industrial technology.

I hope something like that happens because the thing that I fear most about what we’re going to through is the loss of knowledge. As much as we criticize capitalism in this conversation and given the amount we know about the universe and you guys are in a better position to be aware of that than we are in that we know about, The universe is amazing, and I think we might lose all that and go back to a primitive level of knowledge and actually an anti-technology world. I think it’d be a greater tragedy than the loss of people we’re going to face, frankly. So I want to find ways to keep that technological dream alive. And as you say, you’re going to have to be technological to survive in that world anyway. From global knowledge. You’re not not logical.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

From everyone that I’ve talked to, I think that the answer is to start carving things into stone.

 

Steve Keen

As to what?

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Is to start carving instructions into stone because stone will survive the cataclysm?

 

Steve Keen

I know one of my colleagues who I never got around to writing a third edition of Deep Economic, but he wants to publish that on parchment so that it will not decay. And I think that’s a great idea. I’ve got to change my direction. From writing a third edition of Debunking Economics to attacking the idea of economists have done the work on climate change because, again, it’s raising a warning before a crisis, which is what I did before the financial crisis in 2008. Too bad. And everything to write right blog posts about the coming financial crisis.

This is the coming ecological crisis. And the trouble is, you could have even bad economic management could reverse the damage that could minimize the damage of a financial crisis. But there’s nothing that can minimize the damage we’re going to do to the productive capacity of human civilization by the degree of climate change we’re generating right now. By the time we realize that it’s going to be too late to do something on a global scale, so it comes down to local initiatives. Some countries may be able to do it. The small, fairly authoritarian countries like Thailand is a possibility. Cohesive, maybe China, parts of China, though I worry about the food production issues there. But yeah, your little communities may be a bit like the monasteries of the Dark Ages, keeping knowledge alive while the rich turn into a primitive world.

 

Michael Hudson

I don’t think quite barometer out to keep your books going. Baked ceramic tiles. Ceramic tiles on a wall and a pyramid.

 

Steve Keen

I’ll give it a try.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

So I didn’t quite get an answer to my question about what a new state that was more effective and had safeguards against these kind of corruption would look like. Is that something that can actually be established other constitutional level?

 

Michael Hudson

Well, if you realize that economies tend towards a crazy financial polarization and a debt crisis, then you need a regular debt cancellation. You had that for thousands of years in the ancient Near East. That’s why I wrote and forgive them their debt. So, yes, it’s been done before. But if you realize that the ten tendency of economies is to polarize for disequilibrium, not equilibrium, then you have policies that are going to deal with this inevitability of polarization and disequilibrium. So you need a different mathematical basis of economics than you have today. And if you have the right diagnosis, then you have the remedy that’s indicated by it.

 

Steve Keen

I think you also have to have a humanity has to respect life. And we haven’t. We’re destroying life. This is this my overall perspective is that we have to see our role as being custodians of life. And that means reserving a large part of the planet for non-humans. Wilson was talking about the 50% rule that half the planet. Humans should be excluded from half the planet. I actually think that’s excessive. I think there should be 80% of the planet should be excluded from humans. And we do what we can in the 20%. But we know this is the only planet we know of in the solar system, in the universe that supports life. And with what we know now in terms of what of the possibility of habitable worlds elsewhere, it’s extremely rare.

It may be so rare that we’re the only we could be the only one. We might be there. We might be another one, which goes through this whole process of take off, driven by fossil fuels, overwhelming, and collapsing again. Maybe this is the great filter we face in the future, but if we’re going to survive, we have to be aware that life is fragile and and we have to see ourselves. If we are the intelligent species, we have to prevent its breakdown. The long-term thing, as you both know, is sun will become a red giant. And in its evolution towards that, in about a less than a billion years its own, the energy we get from the sun will destroy the oxygen levels in the planet.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

I mean, I see that, in some sense, as the main project of space exploration. Whether people realize that or not, you know, why are we interested in the moon? Because it’ll make a great industrial outpost for establishing longer-range spaceflights and even our search for life. It’s like really motivated by a search for habitable regions of the cosmos that we can explore and potentially set up a backup hard drive for ourselves here.

 

Steve Keen

I think we have to do that. Yeah, I agree. And then that’s like I’m a mushroom cloud on that front, because if you start with five, six, and whether or not the only way you could survive on Mars is by having a highly technological society and an egalitarian one as well, So whether we get there, I don’t think good timing is good. I think we’re going to fail on that one. But you have to ultimately see our role as being able to maintain life and intelligent life. And that’s we should be first and foremost, what humans do.

Everything else should be secondary for to be driven by that objective. And the trouble is that we are so caught up in our own squabbles and our own attempt to see everything as if there’s nothing other than our species on the planet that we’re ending up destroying our capacity to survive on this planet ourselves.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

I feel like it’s very hard for the average person to care about these large issues of species diversification and so forth when they feel like they have a boot on their neck. Like they feel like they don’t have control over the governments. They feel like they don’t have control over the financial institutions. They need to invest in these financial institutions in order to fight inflation to begin with. And so there’s just like a real powerlessness. I mean, the best thing you can do to clean up the planet is to make poor people not poor. Right. You know, we know that people who are not completely under the thumb of privation, like they’re able to actually take care, that’s something they start to care about all of a sudden. And so, in some sense, it seems like the path to a more sustainable ecology is by making people less poor.

 

Steve Keen

Yeah, they’re having an egalitarian. I mean, for example, I was pitching as an Italian guy who’s in charge of attempting to design what would be the colonies on Mars. So I’m being interviewed about this. It’s a YouTube channel, obviously, and he was asked about the social structure. He said it has to be egalitarian.

You can’t have somebody on Mars having 10 or 100 times the space that the average person does. Engineering alone rules it out. And you want to have a society which regards its every person as contributing together. It has to be egalitarian. It has to be shared. And in the long run, that’s if we’re going to have a potential survival as a species, we have to extend that to all of life. And that’s we’ve been nowhere near thinking in that way as a species at the moment. And what worries me is that we won’t get there anyway, that you will end up with the, you know, the religious nutcases taking over again in the aftermath of an industrial collapse caused by climate change, which I blame on technology rather than seeing technology as the potential solution to avoid that world.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Well, interestingly enough, as Michael’s shown in his writing, that the more sustainable economies of, say, the Sumerians were headed by religious nutjobs. That’s quite interesting because they in some sense had a responsibility to some cosmic significance that was beyond the scope of individual sequestering of wealth. And so I wonder if there isn’t something useful about that way of looking at the world.

 

Michael Hudson

Well, all those low surplus economies, or, if not egalitarian, they had checks on egotism. They had checks against the accumulation of wealth. If somebody could get you to let people get wealthy, but you’d have to bury the wealth with them, it wouldn’t be transmitted to the family to become a hereditary wealth. And when people there’d be funerals, and you’d have wealthy people buried with all of their jewelry.

But then, when the funeral is over, you distribute the judiciary all through the people. There are many the anthropology of it shows that all of these societies had checks on this and balances. Of course, some people are going to have big autism. You’re going to have people wanting to get rich, but you’re also going to have society protecting itself against this. And if you’re rich, you have a big feast and you provide food for everybody and and you get social, you get status by being generous, not by being selfish. Not where University of Chicago graduates would do well.

Michael Shilo DeLay

Well, I feel like we have covered a lot of ground. We’ve done three hours here. And one thing I want to ask you guys before you left was who we should be talking to to expand our perspectives on these issues. Who are people that you think are really worth talking to in order to make this an even bigger conversation?

 

Michael Hudson

I think you should talk to Steve Keane.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

I was afraid he said was something. We definitely will.

 

Michael Hudson

I mean, it’s a dilemma, but there are certainly people like E.O. Wilson, as unfortunately, DOD people. I think Juergen Randers, who was the one of the two surviving members of the Limits to Growth study, Dennis Meadows, is still alive and kicking. People working on system dynamics. Microsoft would be embarrassed of I mentioned in here, but his daughter is the leading person in developing a capacity to think in a systemic way. And that’s our failure also to think about the overall system. So there are a range of people out there, but I’ve lost touch in a lot of ways because I’ve been forced to fight neoclassical economists so much. I’ve destroyed my own brain capacity and taking on those bloody idiots. And because you’re fighting this all the time, I’m not trying to track down people who are providing new ways of thinking. So I’m not, unfortunately, because I spend. But I have to fight that battle. I’ve lost touch with the people who are the inspirational thinkers about the future.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Michael, are you in the same boat?

 

Michael Hudson

Oh, yes. I can’t think of. There’s no.. You really need a new science. Not economics, but something that does talk about the whole world as a system. And if you talk about the world of the system, you’ll realize just what Steve’s talking about with this global warming. And this is how economics began in the United States already in the 19.

In the 1840s, you were talking about this and the environmental overhead. Now that had to be included in the national statistics. And the free traders all oppose this. So there’s always been this opposition between reality. People who looked at this system and people who said, don’t look at the system, let us have a cover story. And there just are not many people doing what Steve and I are talking about today because they’re not a discipline. What do we call ourselves? Do we call it? I call myself an archeologist. I used to call myself a futurist when I worked with Herman Cain and Alvin Toffler, and these people. But. Maybe you should call us futurists, but not economists. What do we call it? I don’t know.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

We have Kate Ray was coming in a couple of weeks.

 

Steve Keen

Good. Which is good.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Yeah, I think that’s going to be interesting. We’re also trying to get Nate Hagan’s, but he..

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Met with them last week. We don’t have a podcast on the books yet.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

So if you see him, put in a good word for us.

 

Steve Keen

It will do well the night in our interests fairly regularly.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Excellent.

 

Steve Keen

I’ll do that. Okay.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Thank you, gentlemen. This is been illuminating, and I feel like I get smarter every time I talk to either one of you. So I’ve learned so much.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

And I feel like I get smarter when I talk to both of you at the same time. Yeah.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Exponential.

 

Steve Keen

And I’ve got to, I still have not promoting for the function at all. And I’ve got to do that. I’ve just been overwhelmed. So I’ve got your things to help promote it. But, you know, kick me in the backside occasionally to get me to do something because I’ve just got too much work on.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Definitely, we will. We’re actually taking a little break for a week, and so we’ll have some more bandwidth to think about that. And so we’ll send you some notes.

 

Steve Keen

Okay. Thanks again for the conversation. Good to see you, Michael.

 

Anastasia Bendebury

Thank you both so much.

 

Michael Shilo DeLay

Thank you. All right. Bye, everybody.

Jul 23 Michael Hudson on Debt, Empires, Oligarchs and a More Perfect State

 

Photo by zero take on Unsplash

The post Economists as Hired Guns first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Understanding America’s Post-Industrial Economy

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Wed, 22/11/2023 - 7:28am in

 

GLENN DIESEN: Welcome to today’s program. My name is Glenn Diesen. I’m a professor at the University of Southeastern Norway. With me is my colleague Alexander Mercouris from the very informative and popular Duran.

The guest today is none other than the excellent Michael Hudson, a very renowned economist. He’s written brilliant books, which I can’t recommend enough, on on the industrial economy, the financial economy, the process of debt, empire, collapse. So he’s really one of the great economists of our time.

So the reason we really wanted to talk to him today is because we’re living in an age where the world is undergoing tremendous transformation. I would argue that many of the conflicts and wars we currently have have at least some origin in economics. And what has gone wrong, and what will be the new alternatives coming next, is really something we want to explore today, as we see that the main trend of these days appear to be the relative decline of the West, both the United States and Europe. And we also see the rise of the East, especially then with China at the forefront.

Often the analysis we’re presented with in the media is often limited to GDP, which doesn’t really help us to understand why the US, for example, have lost its competitiveness, its industrial strength, its ability to compete, especially with the Chinese. And while we tend to refer to the Chinese as, you know, a communist country, it has to be pointed out that to a large extent, they appear to resemble the industrial economy of the United States in the 19th century, that of the, especially the American system, I would say. And we don’t have to limit it to China, it appears that Russia is building a similar economic, well, following a similar economic formula, if you will.

So I wanted to hand it over to Michael Hudson first. And I thought we can start off by explaining, I guess, what signifies this US transition from an industrial economy to a financial economy? And why is this so important to understand in terms of what’s happened with debt and the extension or overextension of empire?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, you said that the United States has lost its competitiveness. And actually, it’s worse, the United States decided it didn’t want to compete. And this goes back to the Clinton administration in the 1990s. The Clinton administration’s objective, and that of the Democratic Party, was basically a class war against labor. How do we lower the wages of labor so that we can increase the profitability? Well, the way America had of lowering the wages of labor was, let’s hire Asian labor, especially Chinese labor. Let’s let Chinese into a trade relationship with us into the WTO. And then instead of having to bid up the price of labor in our industrial centers, Detroit and the South and the Midwest, we’ll hire products made by Chinese labor that will keep down wages here. And America can be in a post-industrial economy.

During the 1980s and 90s, all of the economic discussion was, how do you have a post-industrial economy? They didn’t want to industrialize. They thought that industrial labor was blue-collar labor. And in America, you’re not going to have college graduates or even high school graduates wanting to have a blue-collar job. They want a service industry job. They want to make jobs, something that’s not industrial, a managerial job. So a new phrase came into being, the professional managerial class. Technology.

The idea of American economic growth from the 1990s on was, instead of producing manufactured goods, we will develop intellectual property monopolies, especially in information technology, in pharmaceuticals. And America will make its economic growth in GDP, not by making profits to employ labor to produce more and more goods and services, but to have monopoly rents for our pharmaceuticals. So we can make pills that cost 10 cents each and sell them for $500 each. We can make computer programs for automatic artificial intelligence and for computer chips and for all of the information technology we have at enormous markups. And we can live on our economic rents, live off the fat of the land, as they used to say. We don’t have to have blue-collar jobs. Everybody can work in an office and make money that way.

So in a way, what’s happened today is exactly what America wanted. And all of a sudden, they’ve woken up to the fact and said, how can America run the world and be number one if it doesn’t have a manufacturing power, if it’s dependent on other countries for its manufacturing and now for its technology, and if all of this is financed by running into debt that the economy runs up for the military spending abroad to prevent other countries from competing with the United States, when actually it’s the United States that has decided we want you to compete because your production and competition with us is what’s winning the class war against labor. Your competition is what’s holding down the price of labor. So they haven’t really thought, what does a post-industrial economy mean? Well, it turns out to be a financialized economy.

You have today, as the election for 2024 is being prepared, the bewilderment of the Democratic Party here. If you look at the GDP, President Biden says, you’re doing so well, look at GDP. And the vast majority of Americans, according to every poll in every part of the country says, we’re not doing well at all. We’re doing awful. And it turns out that when you look at what is the American GDP, well, almost all of it is the growth in prosperity, the growth in financial benefits for the 1%, maybe for the 10% of the population. And the 1% and the 10% has increased its wealth so much since 2008 led the Federal Reserve to slash interest rates that the 1% and the 10% gain is larger than the loss for the 90%. So all that the President Biden can say is, who are you going to believe? Are you going to look at the statistics or are you going to look at your own life and what you have to spend at the grocery store and what you have to spend on rent and housing as America turns away from a homeowner’s economy into a rental economy?

There’s a huge concentration of land and housing in the hands of absentee landlords instead of private homebuyers who now cannot afford to buy a home when the interest rates are soaring to over 7.5%, in which case, if you buy a home with a 10-year mortgage, in only 10 years, the bank makes more money for the mortgage than the seller of the house makes.

So indeed, America has found that, yes, what is the post-industrial economy? It’s a financial economy. And a financial economy has savings on the asset side of the balance sheet and debt on the liability side. But the savings on the asset side are held mainly by the 1%. And the debt on the liability side is owed by the 99%. So when President Biden said, and the economists profession, Paul Krugman and the Nobel Prize winners all say, well, you don’t have to look at debt because we owe it to ourselves. Well, the we who owe it are the 99%. And the ourselves are the 1%. And that’s what is leading the United States to be not a very happy economy these days.

ALEXANDER MERCOURIS: What you’ve described to a British ear, and I live in Britain, I’m in London, is not completely unfamiliar. I mean, it’s like the kind of cycle that we went through ourselves in Britain. I mean, you had this system that the British created, basically, in the late 19th century. We have commodities flowing in. I think it was Keynes who talked about how if you were a person of certain affluence in Britain, just before the First World War, you could order things from all over the world and they would come to you. And we had a heavily financialized system. We had the Bank of England, we had the City of London, we had our currency pegged to gold. We insisted that people, to a great extent, trade with our currency. We started to neglect our industrial base and rely increasingly on the profits of our empire. And, you know, the rental systems began to take hold.

And one of the things that happened in Britain is that, of course, wealth gradually began to drain upwards. It was like, you know, within the social system you saw some people in late 19th century, early 20th century Britain, becoming incredibly rich and building their houses and buying their Rolls-Royce Silver Ghosts and sending their children to expensive schools and living a very agreeable life. But the rest of the country was going through a time of, shall we say, economic atrophy. And, of course, that happened within a framework of empire and a framework of imperial control.

And it seems to me that’s one of the big differences with the United States today, is that at least with the British they could control it to some extent because they actually had a proper formal empire. The United States doesn’t have it in exactly the same way. So you are grafting a late imperial British structure without having the mechanics of empire as well defined as the British did. Am I getting this completely wrong?

MICHAEL HUDSON: No, you’ve got the point. The explanation of what happened is that empires don’t pay. If you look at Britain in the 1930s, it certainly was solidifying its empire with imperial preference and India and other countries had to save all their money and England. But all of the money that Britain made from its empire ended up being used to pay the United States. So Britain had a surplus with its empire and a deficit with trade with the United States and with U.S. firms.

So it turned out that already in the 1930s, the United States was the beneficiary of the empire. And, of course, that enabled the United States to write the rules of world trade and the the International Monetary Fund and the British loan in 1944 and 1945 so that England had to basically give up its empire to the United States. It had to end imperial preference. It had to introduce free trade and free investment, which meant that India and the empire could spend all the money that they made during World War II anywhere they wanted. Meaning, where did they want to? Well, the only country that had enough industry to give them what they wanted was the United States.

Well, the United States is going through what England went through today. The empire really didn’t pay. And starting with the Korean War in 1951, the United States moved from a position where it started in 1950 with 75 percent of the world’s gold held in the United States. The Korean War pushed the United States into chronic balance of payments deficit. And I’ve done the statistics that I’ve published in Super Imperialism, and the entire American balance of payments deficit was military spending abroad to protect the empire. The private sector in America was just exactly in balance. Trade, foreign investment, borrowing, tourism, all of that was balanced. The entire deficit was military spending, and it felt to lock in the empire. Well, you’re seeing that today accelerating.

And the problem is, how can America finance the military spending abroad? Well, ironically, what happened was the military spending in Vietnam and Southeast Asia forced America off the gold standard, as you know, in 1971. And what were foreign central banks going to do with all of the dollars that were flowing in? They weren’t going to do what General De Gaulle and Germany were doing in buying gold. All they could do was say, well, we have to invest our money in securities. We’ll buy U.S. Treasury securities. And so all the money that America spent abroad militarily was sent back to the United States by the central banks of Europe and other payment surplus countries to finance the balance of payments deficit for the war. So in effect, the whole international monetary system was based on IOUs for America’s military spending across the world.

Well, you can imagine what’s happened today now that the United States has taken a very belligerent position in the world, saying it’s our way or we’re just going to smash things up. The United States, this system, has split the world into two opposing camps, as I think you’ve said on this show. I watch your show regularly, and this is what you’ve been talking about week after week after week, how the world is dividing up and what are the dynamics of this. That’s what you’ve been talking about.

Obviously, other countries think that it’s sort of a crazy international financial system when they’re being threatened by America’s military adventurism of China in the Near East and all over the world. Shouldn’t they have a system that doesn’t rely on the dollar and relies on their own mutual trade and investment? That’s what’s changing the whole world economy today.

ALEXANDER MERCOURIS: Absolutely. And it also is affecting trade flows because, again, and I’m going now back to what the British were doing with their empire, one of the aspects of British imperial preference is, of course, the colonies were obliged to trade with the empire on the empire’s terms, on Britain’s terms. And that did have an effect. It distorted the way the economies performed.

I mean, you can see that in India. One of Gandhi’s, Mahatma Gandhi’s campaigns was about the imports into the way in which the cotton trade between India and Britain worked, and it worked entirely to the benefit of Britain. And it actually was not beneficial to people in India, or so he thought. And beyond a certain point it proved negative for the colonies as well. And they started to push back against this.

And am I wrong in thinking that this is also part of what you’ve just been saying, that they’re saying to themselves, well, look, why should we pay the Americans so that the Americans can threaten us? But also that perhaps they’re also saying to themselves, well, why should we work all the time as, you know, build our factories, work hard in order to provide the Americans with the goods that they want, and at the same time we get money from them which we are expected to recycle back into the United States?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, it’s certainly true that it takes two to tango. But I think the driving force today isn’t other countries pushing back so much, it’s America’s pushing them away. It’s the United States leaving them no alternative but to protect themselves from sanctions, and from the United States simply grabbing their foreign exchanges. It grabbed 300 billion of Russia’s money. It grabbed Iran’s money long ago. It grabbed Venezuela’s gold from the Bank of England. There’s a change of consciousness. There’s a whole awareness that the world needs to have an alternative to the U.S. dollar standard.

And the creation of an alternative means not only not using the dollar, it means creating a different kind of international monetary fund for trade to finance balance of payments and trade obligations among the rest of the world, the global majority. It requires an alternative to the World Bank, not based on privatization of infrastructure, but on public financing of infrastructure to make its prices low, not high, and not at profit opportunities. It means a whole alternative financial system, and a trade system, and probably an alternative to the United Nations, which you see paralyzed these days.

Now, this takes an enormous amount of effort to say, well, it’s really hard to break away from a system based on the U.S., the unipolar system. At least we knew what was happening. It’s hard to create an alternative, but the United States has really forced the issue, and has forced them, China, Russia, Iran, Central Asia, Africa, South America, all realize that we cannot live in this kind of world where the unipolar system is going to take all of our economic surpluses and transfer them to the United States, and has a trade system where we’re depending on American farm exports for our food. We have to be self-sufficient in food. We’re depending on America for all of the technology that we need, and for the oil, so that if America decides to impose sanctions on oil, all of our factories and electric utilities have to shut down. We don’t want to be in a position where other countries can use trade, and finance, and investment as a kind of economic warfare.

This has forced them to accelerate the creation of what really is a new economic order, and that’s what we’re seeing now. A whole different set of institutions that are not, as President Xi and President Putin have said, not unipolar but multipolar. And multipolar means mutual gain for ourselves instead of your gain is our loss, a zero-sum gain, which is the US unipolar strategy.

GLENN DIESEN: I just wanted to ask a bit about what would be an alternative policy for the United States to pursue, because when you spoke about the International Division of Labour, it reminds me to some extent about the British repealing the Corn Laws in the 1840s, the idea being the British should monopolise on manufactured goods and seeking rent from this, and then the rest of the world could compete, driving down the prices on agriculture. But from the 1990s, of course, the United States pushed for monopolising largely on finance and the high-tech industries, so by extending intellectual property rights in return for ceding its manufacturing, as you were speaking about.

But look, 30 years later now, we can assess it didn’t go very well, because all those people in the United States who worked in manufacturing, they didn’t go to high-skill, high-wage jobs, most of them went into retail, so low-skill, low-wage, creating this huge gap within the United States, even intensifying this polarisation between the super-rich and the now super-poor. So this is what happens domestically, but internationally, it wasn’t even able to hold on to this top tier, because the Chinese were climbing up global value chains, and as you pointed out, the response has been to double down, that is, continue the financial economy and also pushing away the rest of the world. So when the Chinese are challenging the US, they’re seizing, blocking their technologies, their chip technologies, they’re seizing the money of the Russian Central Bank, effectively proving to them that they can’t live in this US-dominated system anymore. So it seems they’re doing everything wrong.

So I guess my question is, what would be the right thing to do? What should the United States be doing at this point?

MICHAEL HUDSON: I’m sorry to disappoint you, but there is no right thing that the United States can do. It’s in a trap. It’s in what economists call the optimum position. Mathematicians say it’s optimum because whatever you do is going to make things worse. And the United States has painted itself into a corner. And the only way it could get out of the corner would be to be a different kind of a country, a different kind of an economy.

For instance, as long as the United States has the enormous military spending throughout the rest of the world, that’s going to be pumping dollars into the world economy. And if other countries do not relend this money to the United States Treasury or the US economy, then the dollar is going to go down and down. The United States can’t really compete given the way in which it’s structured, its medical care and its housing and its finance.

For instance, 18% of America’s GDP is on medical spending. If Americans, wage earners, got all of their goods for nothing, all of their transportation, all of their food, all of their clothes for nothing, they still couldn’t compete given the fact that they have to pay an enormous amount of money, about $20,000 a year, just for medical insurance. And the rents in the United States absorb now about 40% of the income of wage earners. Here in New York, the average rent is $4,500 a month. Well, you can imagine, $60,000 a year just for rent. How on earth can the United States finance its trade and its investment when the cost of living and the cost of doing business is so overpriced?

The employers have to pay a large portion of medical care for their employees, and they want it that way. They want a high medical expense for their own labor because that means that workers are suffering from what Alan Greenspan, the Federal Reserve Chairman, called the traumatized worker syndrome. If a worker goes on strike, they don’t get their medical care. All of a sudden, they have to pay enormous medical care. They can’t pay their credit card monthly statement. And in the United States, most wage earners have a negative credit card balance. The credit card balance is 19% flat. But if you miss a payment, the interest rate goes up to 30% or 31%.

Well, just imagine if you’re paying that much money on what you owe, and if your debt is going up and up, you’re not going to have enough money to buy goods and services. So how can America become an industrial country and roll back the time machine and become the industrial economy it was before if it can’t sell to its own population because its wage earners spend their money on health care, on debt service, and on housing. And other countries are defending themselves by producing their own food, their own manufacturers, and they don’t want to be subject to an America that weaponizes its trade and investment as a kind of locking in its unipolar political and military power. It can’t be done.

So the United States doesn’t really have a cure. And it’s decided the one thing that it can try to do, it’s given up on the global majority. The one part of the world that the United States is able to still gain support from is Europe. And that’s why it cut the Nord Stream pipeline. It wanted to make Europe completely dependent on American energy, really to turn it into the kind of dependent colony that England and the Dutch tried to do in centuries past. So it turns out that the post-industrial economy has really elapsed back into the old feudal imperial economy, and it’s just not going to work as long as other countries have a role to play in their own development.

ALEXANDER MERCOURIS: The former colony turns its imperial master into its own colony. There’s a kind of ironic justice, I suppose. But anyway, that is a bleak picture, but it’s understandable, perhaps, that other countries around the world are responding against it. And China never let itself, it seems to me, become part of this system. And the Chinese put together policies which are now being, I think, looked at by many people around the world as potential alternatives.

And I noticed that Xi Jinping, according to the Chinese readout, he actually sort of alluded to this when he spoke to Biden today. He said, you know, we must understand that one thing we do not want to become is what you are. He actually said that. It’s actually there in the Chinese readout. We do not want to supplant or surpass or become like the United States. We are seeking to rejuvenate through a process of modernization ourselves. And it’s quite an interesting set of words, actually. Do you want to talk a little about China? Because it does seem in so many ways to be a country that is not just different, but almost opposite to the way in which the United States has developed, at least in the post-war period.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, words are very important. And we’re dealing with a kind of Orwellian vocabulary here in the United States. Again and again, President Biden has said the United States is a democracy and China is an autocracy. And just yesterday at the end of his meeting with President Xi, President Biden went on television and said, well, I’ve just been dealing with a dictator.

Now, what makes China an autocracy? It’s doing just exactly what the United States, England, Germany, and every other country does. It has public infrastructure investment. It hasn’t privatized its infrastructure. The most important thing that China has done is keep money creation and credit as a public utility so that China doesn’t have to borrow from a wealthy class of bondholders and pay. China can simply print the money to finance its economic growth. So, its economic growth has been self-financing.

Well, the United States says that’s autocratic. The democratic way to do things is the government will borrow from the private sector and that leads the banks to tell the government, we will only give you money if you do what we want to do. So, what the United States calls democracy is what Aristotle and everybody else calls an oligarchy. And the irony is that it’s China that is turning out to be the most democratic country by not having an oligarchy, but by having a central government that pretty much acts with group understanding. The whole central committee, they all talk together. It’s not a one-man rule at all. It’s a very definite idea of what do. We want to provide the core of the economy at the lowest price possible.

Well, you’ve seen what they’ve done with transportation. That’s a public utility as it used to be in England and every other country except the United States to make sure that the cost of transport is as low as possible. Communications is a public utility. Education, in the United States, it costs $40,000 now to get an education. Other countries have free education. So, in the United States now, if you don’t inherit money to pay for your college, if you don’t inherit a trust fund from the 10%, then you have to take on student debt that is so large that once you graduate from college, you cannot afford to buy your own house because the bank will say, I’m sorry, you’re already spending so much money on your student debt that you don’t have enough money to pay the mortgage too. You’re going to have to rent. Well, China avoids that by having free education. It’s medical care. You can go right down the line.

There are certain basic needs that in the United States, and I guess England too now, the labor and their employers have to bear the cost of. They don’t have to do that in China. There’s a certain minimum guaranteed price of living.

The one problem, of course, is that China has not made housing a public utility. And the reason is that as part of China’s policy of let a hundred flowers bloom, it lets economic policy to the localities and to the local districts and cities throughout China. And the theory 30 years ago, 20 years ago, was let every city try to develop its own means of financing. Well, given the cost of building infrastructure, almost all the cities and small towns in China and localities had to finance themselves by selling off land to real estate developers. And so there was an enormous bias in China for financialized housing, just as was occurring in the United States. So the one way in which the Chinese economy has not freed itself from the Western model is in this financialization of real estate.

Well, normally that would not be a problem for China because it itself is the money and debt creator. So China is able to do something that the United States cannot do. If an industrial company or corporation in China has a problem as it had with COVID and can’t pay its debts, it’s not sold off and forced to close down and fire its labor. China writes down the debt. It’s very easy for a government to write down corporate debt when the debt’s owed to itself. Much harder to write it down when the debt’s owed to a private banker who’s going to scream. Well, the same thing in real estate. China basically could write down the debt that Evergrande and the Country Garden and other real estate huge builders and developers have run up, except that for some reason, I think it’s the insistence of the Shanghai neoliberals there. The Chinese government has guaranteed the dollar debt for these companies to issue their debt.

Well, there’s no reason in the first place for them ever to have issued dollar debt because most of the Chinese money was spent at home, except for what it had to import for steel and cement and other building material. But China has done pretty much what the United States’ Fannie Mae has done by guaranteeing the mortgage debt. This ties it in a knot. My guess is what the Chinese government is discussing right now is, now that we’re unable to earn the dollars to pay the dollar debt because of the sanctions that the United States insists on, do we want to remove the government promise, the underwriting for the banks that have guaranteed this dollar debt?

Well, China has the option, and this is its financial atom bomb that it has. It can say, well, we’re terribly sorry. We’re going to let the banks go broke that have made this dollar debt. The real estate companies can’t pay. That means that they’re bad debts. The banks can’t pay. We are going to let them go broke. But of course, we do have, fortunately, deposit insurance for all of the depositors up to, let’s say, some given amount that covers 90% of all of the deposits by Chinese families and workers and businesses, and let the debt go under and start all over again with a clean slate. That, I think, is what logically is being discussed right now in China. And you can just imagine what that’s going to do to the dollar holders.

That, to me, is the ultimate kind of de-dollarization that we’re talking about. And you can just imagine where that’s going to leave not only the United States, but other countries that have tried to hold the wealth of their 1% and their domestic client oligarchies in dollars.

ALEXANDER MERCOURIS: Can I just say about the cheap costs of things? You’re absolutely correct. I went to China, and I was actually…there was an awful lot of things that I saw there. But I saw, for example, the Chinese railway system, the high-speed trains. And I noticed, first of all, that they were both very cheap to travel on, but that they were designed to be that way in the sense that the engineering was exceptional. But you didn’t have this enormously complicated system of first class and second class and third class that you’d have in Europe, the very expensive seats that you would have for people who would pay more. It was all actually both impressive and very functional. And that is something that you noticed right across the board in terms of the goods and services that are supplied to the Chinese population. It was something that, for Britain at least, it was very striking.

And now, coming back to all of this, of course, another country, perhaps the one that Glenn and I know a lot better, Russia, in the 1990s, went in the diametric opposite direction to the one that China took. They privatized everything. They opened up their economy in every conceivable way. They allowed banks, private banks, to be established. They made their currency entirely convertible. They privatized their housing stock, which up to then had been publicly owned. And, of course, what happened was that by the time that Putin became president, we had a small group of people who were immensely rich. They were also extracting rents from the Russian economy. We both saw that. We both saw that for ourselves. You could see immense luxury in Moscow for this small group of people.

They were able, because the ruble was convertible, and the government was propping up the price of the ruble using the oil rents that it was getting. They were able to convert their money into dollars at very preferential rates. And, of course, they were investing that money in the London housing market, in New York, and buying bonds. They were also, of course, taking out loans in the West. So they went in the diametrically opposite direction to the one the Chinese took. Now can you say something about that?

MICHAEL HUDSON: The Russian kleptocracy made its money from economic rent, basically natural resource rent. The United States’ promise to the Russians was, well, if you just give all of the property to the owners, give every factory to the factory manager, give the gas company to the heads of managers of Gazprom, if you give it to them, then nature will take its course and they will all be led by the invisible hand to invest and act just as the United States did. But, actually, this is the exact opposite of every way that the United States got rich. And the Russians did not even have a progressive income tax for all of this.

Well, here’s what happened in 1994, 1995, when Russia decided to privatize, essentially, there was a scheme that was put into its hands to privatize all of the nickel and the raw materials and the oil companies. And so the government borrowed money from the banks. The banks would write a check to the government, let’s say, for $5 billion. The government would take this check, and it pledged as collateral, the holdings and Neurolch nickel and other oil and others. And the government then deposited this $500 billion check back in the bank that wrote it. So the bank wrote a check, it was redeposited there, it was free. The banks created free money. That’s what banks do. They create it on their computers, on a balance sheet. And sure enough, Russia ended up giving all of its natural resource rent to the kleptocrats.

Well, you mentioned that they wanted to get dollars. Well, how do they get the dollars? Here they have the stock in Neurolch nickel and Yukos oil. The only way they can get money from the stock is to sell it abroad in England and America because the Russian savings were wiped out with the hyperinflation. So the Russians didn’t have any ability to buy their own rent-yielding natural resources. Only the foreigners did. And from 1995 to 1997, Russia’s stock market was the leading stock market in the world. And that was because it was a bonanza. It was free money from the public sector.

And if you look at the last 2,000 years of history, almost all the fortunes in every country in every century have been made by getting money from the public sector. Fortunes are made by privatizing what was in the public sector and by insiders giving it to themselves. That’s how the Roman Empire made its money, by seizing land right down to the United States, grabbing land from the Native Americans.

So you had all of this privatization, and needless to say, the kleptocrats’ modus operandi was that of a rentier. It was a rent-seeking economy that the neoliberals advised Russia to do, not a profit-making economy where industrialists would hire labor to produce more goods and services. The fact is that the factories, as you know, stopped paying the labor.

And the one thing that Russia did not privatize and give away freely was the housing. I made three speeches before the Duma in 1994 and 1995, and I brought over America’s former Attorney General Ramsey Clark and others, trying to convince them that you should give everybody their housing, just give it in their own name, then they wouldn’t have to buy it. You’d create at least their own housing, you’d create an internal market. That wasn’t done until very, very late in the game, until a point was reached where the Russians and also the Baltic states and all the post-Soviet states had to pay enormous amounts of money just to get housing, while all of the rest of the land and natural resource wealth was given away freely by the kleptocrats. That was the neoliberal travesty of rentier capitalism.

I think that’s why when you read the speeches of President Putin today or Secretary Lavrov, you can see just the disgust that they feel almost for themselves for ever having been suckered into this kind of neoliberal plan. I think that’s spurred them to say, well, look, we have to turn east, not west. This is how all of Europe and America are making its money. They’re turning into a rentier economy. We’ve seen what that did to us, and as President Putin said, Russia lost more of its population economically in the 1990s as a result of neoliberal rentier policy than it lost militarily in World War II. Well, it’s never going to do that again, and that is what has set its mind so much on to creating an alternative. When there’s a will, there’s a way, and there’s now the will, and that’s been the precondition for creating a much sounder basis for growth in Russia, China, and the rest of the global majority.

GLENN DIESEN: You mentioned the will, but what would be the way, because do you see, I guess, Russia following the same path now as China has? Because when we began this program, I mentioned the American system, because I sometimes feel like this is the model maybe at least China, but also to a large extent, Russia might be following because they were in a very similar situation now as the Americans were in the early 19th century, in which the Hamiltonian economics all transformed itself into this American system where the Americans said, we can’t be dependent on British manufacturing, its infrastructure, ports and such, and its national banks, and later on currency. So they began to develop their own system through a lot of protectionist policies, one would have to add.

And you also saw towards the end of the 19th century how people, I know you referred to many times economists such as Simon Patten, who viewed the idea of building a physical industry that is, well, at least the infrastructure to be something imperative investment for the government to make, because it has a dual effect, on one hand, it makes industries more competitive by having the infrastructure in place, but it’s also something that elevates the standard of living for the average citizen. So it seems at least for the Chinese that physical industries has been a key focus of its economic policy.

But I was therefore curious if it’s the same in Russia, because the same three pillars of the American system, I seem to see it in both countries, in one hand, where they seek technological sovereignty, that is what Alexander Hamilton would have focused on manufacturing. But now of course, they look at digital platforms and their own, well, it was in critical industries and technologies that there’s some level of autonomy, they both seek this very vast infrastructure projects to find new areas of connectivity to avoid, you know, American choke points. And last, they both focus on de-dollarization, their own banks, to not end up paying all the rent to the not just Americans, but the Europeans as well.

So I was just curious if you can say something about this. Do you see Russia effectively having learned its lesson from the 90s and following that path or what is the way that the Chinese and Russians are going?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, both the Russian economy and the Chinese economy are operating on an ad hoc basis. There’s no economic theory or doctrine that either countries develop to explain what they’re doing. In fact, China is still sending its economic students to the United States where they’re taught neoliberal financial policy. And my students tell me that the American educated students get priority in being hired over domestic students.

So China and Russia are acting pragmatically in a way to create an alternative to the neoliberal growth. But they don’t have, they haven’t systematized it in the way that industrial capitalists in the United States and England spelled out. Here’s our strategy. Here is our set of laws that we have.

I guess you could say what President Putin is doing is jawboning the kleptocrats, the wealthy class saying, okay, you can keep your money, but you have to invest it in ways that we agree will help the Russian economy become self-sufficient, independent, productive and more prosperous. So it’s all done on an ad hoc basis.

One of the problems is that Russia by the 1990s was probably the only country in the world that had no background in Marxism at all. Largely, this was a result of Stalin’s popularization of volume one of Capital to say, well, capitalism is an exploitation of workers by their employers. Well, all that indeed was in volume one, but Marx wrote volume two and three all about finance and rent seeking. And the one thing that Russia did not see coming in the 1990s was rent seeking and financialization and simply using the banks as a means of creating and backing monopolies as their source of income in a non-industrial way.

Marx would have called this a pre-industrial way. And Marx said, well, the revolutionary contribution of industrial capitalism was to free Europe from feudalism, from the legacy of feudalism, from the hereditary landlord class. We’re going to get rid of the landlords so that there can be popular ownership. And yet there’s still, they never got rid of land rent. But land rent is now, instead of being taxed away as the tax base, it’s paid to the banks as mortgage interest in the United States. And in Russia and China, if you want to buy a house, the land rent still, as China becomes more prosperous, people can afford to pay more and more for the housing they buy. And this, they take out a larger loan in order to buy the house and the rent is paid to the bank.

So China is letting a rentier financial sector develop in its midst because it hasn’t really defined what is the model of growth that we want to have. They’re doing it by experimentation, ad hoc, I think. And what needs to be done and what obviously is going to emerge in the kind of, is a consciousness of how are they going to make the economy more productive, more efficient, and use the economic surplus to raise living standards instead of to create a wealthy rentier financial and rent-seeking landlord class monopolist that you’re seeing in Europe and the United States.

ALEXANDER MERCOURIS: The interesting thing is, when you say ad hoc, you’re absolutely correct in the sense that in Russia you get the sense that at the very high level of government, Putin himself, very frustrated right from the outset with a neoliberal model, but at the same time very intimidated by the oligarchs around him, very, very wary of taking on neoliberals within the finance ministry and the central bank, but at the same time as if frustrated himself and going gradually, ever so gradually, with the grain of what is needed to try to bring the system back to some kind of stability.

So you can see this. You can see this, for example, in the banking system. I mean, the banking system, which people don’t know about this or think much about this, I mean, the banking system has been changed completely in Russia over the last 30 years. I mean, it’s become…it had become almost completely private. The Sverbank was still functioning as a state bank, but there was always the possibility that it would be privatized. Now, we’ve gone from a largely private banking system with banks…a Russian banker once said to me, Russian banks are black holes, they’re black holes in the economy, they are a disaster as they are. We’ve gone from a private banking system to one that is almost entirely state-owned.

There are a few Russian private banks still, but the big banks, the really important ones, are state-owned. We’ve also…but we’ve also had other things happening. We have now the emergence of industrial policy. But all of this has been reactive, and to some extent it’s been…it’s happened in response to pressure from the West. So we have financial sanctions, which in effect almost oblige the sort of state control of the financial system. We’ve had a shift in the way in which the ruble is managed from, you know, policy go full convertibility towards now we’re getting capital controls coming back. We’re starting to see a kind of protectionism imposed on the economy from the outside. But it is all completely reactive up to this time.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, I think that ad hoc policy was deliberate, certainly in China’s case. In the 1970s, I was working for a number of U.S. government agencies as an economic advisor, and I talked to a Chinese official, the representative of the World Bank, and he said, look, we really love the ideas you have. We’ve got to bring you over to Shanghai for our Futures Institute there, and, you know, tell us a bit about your background.

Well, I told him about my background, and I grew up in a Marxist family. My father was a political prisoner in the United States. And the Chinese official said, oh, dear, I think you’d better not go to China. The one thing they don’t want is anyone with a Marxist background. They want to really develop something new. And I could understand why, because they thought that most people with a Marxist background were the old Stalinist types.

The one thing China did not want to do was follow the old central planning of Russia. They wanted to have a hundred flowers bloom, and they thought that anyone that had a Marxist background, that I would be in favor of that kind of centralized planning. Well, I wasn’t, but they actually said my life might be in danger. They didn’t want me to interfere in domestic Chinese affairs, so I didn’t go. And I could understand why they did this.

The irony is that what really helped China develop so much was none other than the great destroyer of American capitalism, Milton Friedman and the Chicago School, that the Shanghai people had Milton Friedman come over and talk about the free market and all of that. And the one thing that Friedman and the Chicago boys were able to convince China was they’re always going to be ambitious, intelligent people that see a need for something that governments can’t really innovate. Let there be innovation. Let people try to make money everywhere. And if they succeed, let them succeed up to a point and get wealthy up to a point. Let them follow it. And then you decide who to help and who to subsidize and how to join in. But you become their financiers, not private financing. That actually worked.

You had that with Deng’s policy, black cat, white cat, as long as they catch mice, that’s the important thing. Well, that ad hoc policy is what enabled China to end up making good judgment because the judgment was done by a pretty large central committee that ended up having good judgment as to what industries to support, like your high speed rail that you mentioned and other industries. So it all worked out.

Now that it’s working out in their ad hoc way, I think it would be the next step is for them to say, here is why it’s worked out. It’s worked out because here are the basic principles that we want to have as an economic platform, whether you call it socialism or industrial capitalism or something entirely different. The name doesn’t matter, but it would be we really should tie it together into the new economic system that for Russia, China, Eurasia as a whole, and the whole global south, too.

That’s what we’re waiting to see, and I think it’s going to be very much like what happened in the 19th century in British classical political economy, a distinction between profits and rent, a distinction between earned income and unearned income, and productive labor and unproductive labor, and public finance versus private finance. I think all of this is about to be codified, and it would really help if people would look at… All of this has been discussed for a century in the 19th century, and you’re not going to…

In America, they’ve dropped the whole history of economic thought from the economics curriculum because, as Margaret Thatcher said, there is no alternative, and the way you make sure there’s no alternative is you don’t let any knowledge that there was an alternative, and that used to be industrial capitalism, that people can develop.

GLENN DIESEN: Well, I just wanted to comment more than a question. I think it seems like the ideology of capitalism kind of narrowed in what it could actually mean, because the industrial capitalism we had, it seems to have almost been hijacked by the ideology these days, because whenever we speak about capitalism now, we only serve one version, which is the one of Friedrich Hayek or Milton Friedman, and often people use the examples of Adam Smith or David Ricardo to suggest this is the ideological foundation of capitalism.

But David Ricardo, in his book, he even wrote, to much of his surprise, that yes, with every technological innovation, the return of investment will concentrate in the hands of the capital, upsetting the balance with labor. So he did recognize this, and he had the same with Adam Smith, of course. He was recognizing also that yes, the hidden hand or maximum flexible economy is very efficient in order to get more increased revenue. However, he also recognized that once the economy grows, there should be some reforms to capitalism to support and help the poorest, so you don’t have this very uneven distribution.

Even if I’m not mistaken, Adam Smith was also a bit cautious about the development of rent seekers in the economy, someone who can take away and essentially not just take profits away from production, but thereby also making production less competitive. So again, a lot of what problems the United States have today, in which you have an oligarchy class siphoning off wealth, and in the process, making the entire American economy less productive.

But it seems that whenever we talk about capitalism today, this is the Friedman Hayek version, this is the only interpretation, and the alternative would mean that you would be a Stalinist, a Marxist, or something on completely the other side of the spectrum. Did you see any of this changing perhaps? Any other intellectual emerging in who’s able to make distinction between industrial capitalism and financial capitalism? Like a Friedrich Liszt of our time, someone, or another pattern?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, you said the magic word, rent. But Adam Smith, Ricardo, John Stuart Mill, and Marx and the others were all talking about with value and price theory. And they defined price as the excess of the price over the intrinsic cost value of products. And that difference of price in excess of value is economic rent.

And the objective of Adam Smith and Ricardo was to say, rent is unearned, it’s a special privilege, it’s a carryover from feudalism, and a historical task of industrial capitalism is to free society from economic rent. And that is why the concept of exploitation in the form of rent culminated in Marx.

The fight against Marxism is a fight against Adam Smith and Ricardo. And what Marx did was push Ricardo, Smith, Malthus, John Stuart Mill to its logical conclusion. And Marx showed how all of this was moving towards socialism, meaning a rent-free economy, where everybody earned what they produced and there was no free lunch.

What happened, of course, was that the rent-seekers fought back. And by the 1890s, you had the Austrian school, reactionary school that became the von Misesians and the Hayek people in Austria. And you had in America John Bates Clark saying there is no difference between rent, there’s no difference between price and value. Economic rent doesn’t exist. Everybody earns whatever they want, whatever they get, no matter how they earn it. And that has become the basis of national income accounting.

So if you look at the gross national GDP accounts of the United States and Europe, they count economic rent as if it’s an addition to product, to GDP. Interest charges, late charges are an addition to GDP. The rise in the rents paid by people as the rents go up for their housing is all GDP. They’ve erased the entire thrust of classical economics distinguishing between earned and unearned income. And, of course, that is exactly what China, Russia, and the rest of the world want to distinguish.

They want to have an economy where people are productive, not where fortunes are made by being parasitic rent seekers making money in their sleep, as John Stuart Mill defined landlord rent and landlord capital gains. And as it turns out, the one thing that GDP does not report is capital gains. In other words, the increase in the price of wealth, the increase in the price of assets. Most wealth in the United States and Europe is not made, and certainly in Russia, was not made by producing more goods and services. It was by increasing the value of the property you had, the real estate property, the stocks and the bonds, the rent privileges that let you take the money you make from oil or nickel or diamonds or other products.

What is needed is a set of economic statistics that actually will tell Russia, China, and other countries how much that we’re producing is actual product and how much is overhead. The Western GDP and post-classical theory denies that there’s any such thing as economic overhead. Monopoly pricing is not an overhead. Higher rents is not an overhead. That’s the one thing that in ad hoc practice Russia and China are trying to minimize.

Well, this intuitive behavior that they’re doing should be reflected in a recasting of economic statistics along just exactly the lines that they’re doing. That’s what I’m waiting for. Most of my effort in talking to the Chinese and the articles that I’m publishing there and the articles I’ve done in Russia through the Academy of Sciences have all been on this topic.

MICHAEL HUDSON: I think that you’re making some progress, actually, because I remember a couple of years ago going to Perm, which is in the Urals, visiting the university there, and meeting people in the economics departments. And they were starting to talk about this there. I mean, there was…I remember a sort of, you know, discussion on these very topics.

And partly, and I’m sure this is partly a consequence also of recent experience in Russia, because rent there was so crude and savage, you know, the sense of rent-taking from the economy. It was so open, and the people who were the rentiers, the oligarchs, were so…are so disliked that it almost set itself up, if you like, for people to start to argue against it and to sort of tilt against it. And yet the power of these people within Russia has managed to slow down processes of change to a very great extent.

And it’s…one of the great paradoxes is that you see that the West has actually been helping, in a kind of curious way, those people in Russia… and this is talked about in Russia itself…who wanted to see things like this change. So Russia obliged to buy its aircraft from the West, from the United States, from Boeing, from Airbus. Now they’re no longer able to do that, so they have to make their own aircraft. And they discovered remarkably they actually do have the resources and the skills of people who know how to make aircraft.

The same is starting to happen in the machine building and machine tools industries. They were importing them from the West, now they’re having to start making them themselves. They’re having a kind of protection system imposed on them. They’re finding also that the oligarchs who are so powerful…actually, they’re not really that powerful at all, after all. They are, in fact, people who are unpopular because they’re seen as pro-Western. But the very fact that they were keeping so much of their money in the West is starting to undermine them.

And it is this very strange thing which…I wonder whether people in the United States have understood the extent to which they’re actually propelling Russia in a direction which many, many people in Russia, including, I think, Putin himself, always wanted to go but which they were very afraid to go towards.

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, the policymakers certainly do not understand it, because suppose that there is somebody in the State Department or the blob that does understand what you’ve said. They will be called, well, you’re not a team player. What we say goes. We’re the exceptional country. Whatever we say can do. You know, I think you’d be happier with another job. So, not understanding what’s happening is a precondition for keeping your job in the State Department and the blob. That’s the irony. And it’s all working out for the best. You’re right. Where would Russia be without President Biden urging it on?

GLENN DIESEN: I just want to add, because I completely agree with both of you, because if you look at the policies in which large industrial economies have emerged, they’ve hardly ever been on completely unfettered or free markets, completely, and not neoliberal at least. You see, from the West to Japan, you always had the recognition that if you want to have a free competition in international markets, you have to be able to compete. So, in other words, you provide temporary subsidies and tariffs for protection to build up your infant industries vis-à-vis the mature industries in the international markets.

And, of course, sometimes this is, well, historically, at least from the 19th century in the West and Japan, we had to have policies specifically to protect them. But this, with the sanctions, not just against the Russians, but the Chinese as well, this has imposed the development of infant industries. I mean, look at the Chinese chip industry. This is amazing. They would have to have some very unexpected… The Americans threatened to… Well, they did cut off their access to chips. And now the Chinese, in record time, were able to provide all the funding and subsidies and essentially remove this whole huge industry, which was dependent on the United States, brought it under complete technological sovereignty, sovereign control over it.

And now this is, yeah, almost… Well, they were already going this direction, of course, but forcing them to accelerate it. And, again, I see the same in Russia from agricultural products, their cheeses, their digital ecosystems emerging, machine tools across the border, banks, the trading in their own currencies. All of this would have taken maybe 10, 20 years, and it was pushed down to two years to accelerate this process simply out of necessity. But, yeah, I very much agree with Michael Hudson also that this was something that became a requirement, forced. And given that they don’t have specific policies driving this direction, often reacting on an ad hoc manner, I think there’s little recognition for how we contributed to this decoupling from the West ourselves.

Anyways, I keep noticing we may be running out of time soon. So before we wrap up, shall we… I’ll pass on the word to you guys.

ALEXANDER MERCOURIS: Just one question I really wanted to ask. It’s the very last one, because you talk about the conceptual that they haven’t yet worked out, either in China or in Russia, an alternative system of economic thought. And this is potentially, in some ways, a dangerous thing.

But both Glenn and I, I think, have noticed that in Russia they’re now suddenly rediscovering Friedrich List. And Friedrich List was very much, in late 19th, early 20th century Russia, the dominant economic thinker. Not just Sergei Witte, who was the finance minister at that time, who was an open, declared disciple, but if you read, for example, the sort of economic courses that the foreign ministry school in Russia used to teach, very much based on List, looking at the American system as well of the 19th century, saying this is the model that, you know, Russia should follow. And we both, I think, noticed that the Russians are suddenly looking back and thinking about him.

I mean, I haven’t read List. I should make that very clear. Is he someone that perhaps might provide some of the answers, some of the framework, or is it just a case of, you know, nostalgia for another time, which you do unfortunately also see in Russia?

MICHAEL HUDSON: Well, List was the first generation of American protectionists. He developed his ideas in the United States with Matthew Carey in the 1820s. But then he went to Germany, where, of course, he really developed his theory that Germany needed railroad infrastructure and it needed a belt and road initiative, basically. So I think it was via Germany that List got to Russia.

But the second generation of protectionists in the 1840s and 50s in the United States went way beyond List. And so they translated List’s book and said, well, he didn’t really take into account, he didn’t really spell out how you needed to develop an industrial system based on high wage labor. You need to raise labor productivity by raising its wages and making it healthier, better clothed, better housed, and all of that. So List was only stage one of the protectionists. And I wrote a book on this, America’s Protectionist Takeoff, where I talk about List and his followers.

I want to say one thing about what Glenn said about the U.S. that is relevant to this. The U.S. never takes into account that other countries may have a reaction to what the United States does. They’ve missed the boat every time. They had never dreamed that Russia would have an alternative or China would have an alternative as to what to do. And that’s because they don’t think of economics in the United States as a system.

For them, a market exists without government playing any role at all, without policy playing any role at all. And if you don’t have a market, then, of course, there isn’t a system. There’s just a free-for-all and a grabitization. And yet economics in the 19th century was a system. That’s what Marxism is all about. Economics is social and political. That’s why the British called their works political economy. Ricardo’s book was Principles of Political Economy, not a market economy.

And so this free enterprise market idea that governments should not play any role at all, any subsidy, and certainly shouldn’t tax, this anti-government idea has put blinders on American foreign policy, so they have no imagination that Russia could do exactly what [Alex] is talking about, that, of course, they’ve done, as any reasonable person would have done, as China has done. That’s the irony of all this.

So I’m glad that, yeah, I think that Frederick List is probably in the Russian libraries, the most widely held book on protectionist ideas, but also Glenn mentioned Japan’s productive policy. The American leading protectionist in the 1850s was William Seward, the Secretary of State Seward’s law partner, Erasmus Peshine Smith. And the Americans waited for the British ambassador to Japan to go back to England for a vacation, and then Peshine Smith went to Japan, became an advisor to the Mikado, and they translated all of the American protectionist works, and that became the guideline for how Japan developed its protectionism in the late 19th century.

Something like that has to happen in Russia and China, but it’ll have to be by way of people reading the books, because there’s no one living that’s going to go there. So all we can do is recommend books for them to read and to include a history of economic thought and say, how did other countries cope with a problem that Russia has today? How did other countries grow and replace England to be free of England’s control of international trade? Let’s see how other countries did it, and we’ll see what works and what doesn’t work.

GLENN DIESEN: Yes, that’s the reaction you referred to, because when Peshine Smith went to Japan by invitation, the Japanese, of course, have been looking at horrors with Britain destroying China in the opium wars from the 1840s to 60s. So this is, again, a reaction to the system changing around them.

Any final words before we wrap this up?

ALEXANDER MERCOURIS: This has been a stimulating discussion. We could have gone on for hours, I think, but I think this is a good place to stop because, you know, we’ve also discovered, I mean, I didn’t know about this, that there’s this body of economic thought. Perhaps somebody should write to the Kremlin and tell them, and to Zhong Nanhai.

MICHAEL HUDSON: That’s your department, I think.

GLENN DIESEN: Thanks as well. I really appreciate it. This was immensely interesting.

MICHAEL HUDSON: I’m glad we picked up a topic that isn’t on most discussion blogs.

GLENN DIESEN: Thanks again.

Photo by PAN XIAOZHEN on Unsplash

The post Understanding America’s Post-Industrial Economy first appeared on Michael Hudson.

Pages