Banking

Error message

  • Deprecated function: The each() function is deprecated. This message will be suppressed on further calls in _menu_load_objects() (line 579 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/menu.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Notice: Trying to access array offset on value of type int in element_children() (line 6600 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).
  • Deprecated function: implode(): Passing glue string after array is deprecated. Swap the parameters in drupal_get_feeds() (line 394 of /var/www/drupal-7.x/includes/common.inc).

Platforms, Payments, and Ponzi Schemes

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 02/05/2024 - 4:10am in

Electronic platforms can also be thought of as a distinctive type of “terrain” that, like land, can define specific types of revenue and power for those who control them. ...

Read More

From “Boring” to “Roaring” Banking

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Mon, 29/04/2024 - 10:00pm in

Harder to measure, but no less crucial, is Epstein’s identification of the intellectual “capture” of both the academy and policymaking institutions—their infiltration by financial interests and the economic paradigms that prop them up. ...

Read More

Welfare for the wealthy

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Sat, 20/04/2024 - 5:11pm in

I posted this video on YouTube this morning:

The transcript is:

I am deeply offended by welfare for wealthy people.

Now I don't particularly like the term welfare because I think that ‘social security’ or ‘benefits’ are much better terms than welfare, but it happens to work quite nicely in the context of making payments to the wealthy that they don't deserve.

What payments am I talking about? Well, since 2021, the Bank of England has increased its base rate of interest from 0.1 per cent to 5.25 per cent. And as a consequence, as we all know, vast amounts of extra interest has been charged in the UK on those who have had to borrow.

Mortgage holders are paying more.

People who pay rent pay more because their landlords, by and large, have mortgages.

And we're also paying more for many products that have interest implicit within them. Car loans, for example.

On the other side of the equation - and there is always another side of the equation in economics - somebody is benefiting hands down. Who's benefiting? Well, the owners of the wealth on which interest is paid are benefiting.

The interest rate went up from 0.1 per cent to 5. 25 per cent. It's unusual for anybody to have earned 5.25 per cent on their deposits, of course, over that period. But real interest rates have risen from well under 1 percent in 2021 to over 4 percent still if you search around. In other words, the wealthy have benefited enormously from the welfare that has been provided to them by the Bank of England's benevolence, which is biased in their favour.

That means they have vastly more income available to them at present, whilst those who have had to borrow to live and those on lower income - those who are younger by and large - have had much less. This has had a serious economic impact. The wealthy are, in effect, of course, able to spend more right now and have still been fueling inflation, despite the Bank of England's efforts to increase interest rates to suppress inflation.

Counterintuitively, they have, in fact, even more cash to spend and, therefore, have the most impact upon inflation - the consequence being that inflation has not gone away as fast as was anticipated.

It's bizarre. We have literally created a system where inflation control doesn't work, interest rates don't achieve the desired outcome, but the rich get richer.

What a great surprise. And what a news story that is. A news story that's not being said on any of the mass media, which is why I thought I'd mention it here.

The young, the poorest and the most financially vulnerable are bearing the burden of the Bank of England’s folly

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 18/04/2024 - 4:17pm in

Inflation might be lower. But some things are still shooting upward in price, entirely as a result of the reckless interest rate increases that were wholly unnecessary put in place by the Bank of England.

As the FT reports this morning:

The FT does have the decency to apportion blame for this. It is not landlords, per se, who are exploiting their tenants (although those without gearing undoubtedly will be). Many are passing on the extra costs that they have suffered as a result of the Bank of England’s deliberate policy of penalising UK society for inflation that was not of its creation, and which interest rate raises can do nothing to eliminate.

The result is that the young, the poorest and the most financially vulnerable are bearing the burden of the Bank’s folly, that they are set to continue fur as long as possible.

I have said before, and no doubt will say it again, that economic callousness rarely comes more obviously than this. And I have to use that word. Indifference will not do. The Bank is not indifferent. It knows what it is doing, who it is doing it too and the hardship it is causing and it is planning to continue with it knowing all that because this is the outcome that they desire. And that is unforgivable.

But so too are the politicians who are letting this happen.

Asset Allocation And Banking

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Thu, 18/04/2024 - 12:10am in

Note: This article would hopefully be worked into my banking manuscript. I think it overlaps other article(s), but I wanted to see how this line of argument looks. Needless to say, I have no put the articles into a single document…

One of the difficulties with understanding banking is that one needs to use relatively complex macro models to see how the formal banking system interacts with the non-bank financial system. Analysis based on looking at the motivations of a single bank or based on models where only the formal banking system exists will be misleading. Stock-flow consistent (SFC) models are one of the few attempts at such a modelling framework.

Asset Allocation the Result of Portfolio Choices

In a discrete time SFC model — or a mainstream model — all variables within a time period are determined simultaneously as the result of the model equations. The term “equilibrium” is poorly defined in mainstream macro, but one often sees phrasing that could be interpreted as the determination of the solution is some form of “equilibrium.” Heterodox economists have a bee in their bonnet about the term “equilibrium,” but if we do want to have a mathematical model of the economy, it needs to have a solution in order for it to be of any use.

(One alternative would be to have a model that attempts to model the economy transaction-by-transaction. Although such models might have some theoretical interest, they will have too many free parameters to be useful for understanding the economy.)

Although the equations are solved simultaneously, in practice, we can think of the solution happening in two steps.

  1. We determine all the real economy variables — e.g., aggregate wages, consumption, etc. — along with pricing variables that effect the real economy (such as interest rates in some models).

  2. Given the net cash flows created by the economy and pricing, the private sector allocates its portfolio among the model’s financial assets based upon some portfolio allocation rule.

Although the portfolio allocation may appear to influence the pricing variables, this may not always be the case. For example, the central bank may use a so-called “Taylor Rule” for setting the policy rate, and the allocation between money/bonds will be the one consistent with that rule-determined policy rate.

Simplest Model: Government Liabilities Only

Most standard SFC/mainstream economic models just have government liabilities as the financial assets: “money” and “bonds.” (The bonds are typically 1-period bills). Normally, “money” has a 0% interest rate, which makes them distinguishable from the bills that pay the policy rate. This corresponds to a fiat currency (i.e., currency is not pegged to an external instrument).

Since there are no other financial assets, the government cannot issue liabilities to purchase them. As such, the growth in government liabilities is entirely the result of the fiscal deficit (including interest payments). The private sector allocates between “money” and “bonds” based on a money demand function. (If the objective is to maximise returns, the private sector would just hold bills. Since all transactions occur simultaneously, there is no need for “money” for transactions within the model logic.)

Unless some arbitrary rule is inserted into the model to force a default, the fiscal deficit is self-financing: the liabilities issued as a consequence of the deficit are automatically held by private sector. Since there is no peg, government liabilities cannot be exchanged for anything else. All the private sector can do is swap back and forth between the liabilities issued by the government.

Extension: Formal Banking Only

We can then extend the model to include a formal banking system. There is the government liability allocation, and on top of that, banks issue loans and gather deposits. This model quite often shows up in heterodox discussions of banking, as the balance sheets and transactions are easy to describe.

The flows for government liabilities are not affected by this. We just add banks to the list of actors in the model that hold government liabilities. Those liabilities still only can be exchanged for other government liabilities when dealing with the government sector (although private sector actors can trade government liabilities for private sector financial assets).

Unlike government liabilities, bank deposits can be exchanged for the liability of a non-bank: customers can exchange deposits for government-issued notes and coins. If there was a wave of such redemptions, we get the spectre of bank runs — people lining up to get cash out of the banks. Although this scenario fires the popular imagination, it is not that plausible a scenario for large banks. (If non-banks were allowed to bank at the central bank, we could then get a large scale bank run on private sector banks.)

Deposits are created by bank lending and deposits of governmental liabilities by bank clients. By extension, transactions in the opposite direction (repaying loans, transfers to the government from clients) reduce deposits. Inter-bank transfers between clients will result in a transfer of deposit assets, with the involved banks needing to transfer cash through the payments system.

For simplicity, let us assume that there are no reserve requirements. All banks start and end the business day with a zero balance with the payments system/central bank. This means that all inter-bank transfers have to sum to zero (unless there is a bank default that unbalances the system). The implication is that if a bank experiences net outflows from the action of its customers, it must make offsetting transactions to gain the lost cash flows back. Conveniently, for every dollar a deficit bank loses, there is an offsetting surplus of a dollar somewhere else in the banking system. In the case of this model, the banks would either lend in the interbank lending market or buy/sell government securities to allow the offsetting transactions.

This creates the self-financing property of pure formal banking systems: in the absence of capital constraints, the banking system can deliver whatever nominal loan growth the economy can support. Although this idea raises the hackles of some of the critics of heterodox banking analysis, it is an obviously needed property of the banking system. If nominal constraints on loan growth existed, high inflation would result in bank loans effectively disappearing as a percentage of GDP. And saying that the bank system need deposits to fund the loan growth ignores that the deposits are created by the loan extension.

Adding reserve requirements appears to add a brake on loan growth — but that would require the central bank to be willing to allow the interbank rate spike far above a target rate if there were shortages of reserves. Even during the “Monetarist Experiment” in the late 1970s-early 1980s, central bank behaviour was not that extreme. They instead let interbank rates rise, but in a loosely controlled manner. The hope was that the higher interest rates would slow money growth in the future.

The alleged weakness of the “self-financing bank lending” story is that individual private banks cannot allow its lending grow so fast that it loses all its liquid assets used to cover redemptions. Although that is true, but all this implies that banks cannot grow much faster than the average bank growth rate — faster growing banks will tend to lose cash flows to the slower growing ones. (The recipient of a loan will tend to transfer the proceeds to others, who may bank with other banks. This means that loans are expected generate cash outflows. However, if other banks are growing their loan books at the same time, a bank should expect to have inflows from those other banks’ customers.) However, bankers tend to run in a herd, and so overall system can generate ever-faster loan growth by each bank taking turns increasing their own loan book growth. Banks that refuse to relax lending standards in line with competitors will end up losing market share and thus increasingly economically irrelevant. Although the banking system cannot generate “infinite” growth, it can still keep up with whatever the nominal GDP growth rate is.

The logical problem with this model is that the non-bank asset allocation looks somewhat problematic if all deposits are demand deposits. Why would anyone hold large amounts of bank deposits that pay 0% if there are government bills/bonds that pay a positive interest rate? As such, some of the deposits would have to be interest-bearing in order to generate a sensible asset mix for the household sector and the non-bank business sector.

Add a Non-Bank Financial Sector

The final modelling stage is to add a non-bank financial sector. For our purposes, that just refers to bond and money market trading (and not whatever the current silliness is going on in the financial sector). These non-bank instruments can be viewed as extensions of the banking system (hence “shadow banks”), but their behaviour is different.

What these instruments do is add new instruments for the nonfinancial sector’s asset allocation decision. Unlike the previous cases, they can flee government liabilities as well as bank deposits. This creates cash flows from bank customer actions that need to compensated for.

In some cases, the buyer may pay with a bank deposit, and the seller/issuer may put the proceeds into a bank deposit — which leaves the amount of deposits in aggregate untouched. But this will not always be case. In particular, banks issue bonds and money market instruments. The customer will lose a bank deposit asset and replaces it with a bank’s non-deposit liability.

This explains why banks in the real world have to diversify their funding sources: individual banks are going to be losing deposits to the bond and money markets, and so they need to tap into those markets themselves in order meet those outflows. Bank bonds and money market instruments are more attractive portfolio assets than bank deposits, and so bank liability issuance has to match up with the desired asset structure of bond/money market investors. Although a small bank could finance itself with just equity and (term) deposits, this is not going to be an option for the overall banking system in a country that has developed private bond and money markets of any size.

The structure of bond issuance seems to suggest that they are not self-financing in the same way as bank lending. The issuer expands their balance sheet by issuing a new bond liability, and it gets a corresponding cash inflow. That seems to imply that there had to be pre-existing “money” to pay for the bond. However, things are more complex.

  • The buyers of the bond may be using non-bank credit sources to pay for the bond.

  • The issuer of the bond may immediately reinvest the proceeds of the bond issuance into money market or bond market instruments.

The result is that we could theoretically see bond issuance just growing balance sheets outside the formal banking system, even if payments are routed intraday through the banking system. In turn, this means that the non-bank financial system is also able to grow through nominal size thresholds.

The growth of mortgage-backed securities outstanding across the developed world was the result of these considerations. If mortgages were left on bank balance sheets, the balance sheets would have been increasingly strained, as bond investors — flush with retirement savings — would have balked at increasing their concentration risks in bank bonds. By pushing the mortgages of their balance sheet, bond investors were presented with what are supposed to be safe investments that are shielded from the business risks of banking. Oldsters leaving the housing market pushed the proceeds into fixed income funds that indirectly financed the purchases by youngsters. The banks were just in the middle to service the mortgages and (theoretically) assess credit risks.

QE

The wacky New Keynesian central banker practice of buying large quantities of government bonds — Quantitative Easing (QE) — unbalances private sector asset allocations. To the extent that private banks sell their government bond holdings to the central bank, this is just a swap of one government liability (a bond) for another (deposit at the central bank). However, private bank holdings of government bonds are not large enough to meet the deranged level of purchases seen, so the ultimate sellers would be bond holders who used primary dealers as intermediaries. Those bond holders would end up with bank deposits as an asset — and their bank would have a corresponding deposit at the central bank (“reserves”) to compensate for this. Although most institutional bond holders would do compensating trades so as to not end up with bank deposits, somebody else has to end up holding the deposits (to the extent that they are not replaced by other bank liabilities, or bank loans paid down).

Although bank deposits are great for meeting potential transaction needs, they are a terrible portfolio asset. The yield on them is administered by the bank. And unless the investor sets up deposit relations with multiple banks, they will end up with concentrated credit risk. The situation is slightly better for the banks: they end up with a lot of cheap deposit funding. However, there is no reason to believe that such deposits will be sticky, since they are in excess of what was seen as being needed to cover transaction needs. The bloating of bank balance sheets could stress some regulatory ratios.

It also does little to contain banking system stress. The risk is a bank becomes insolvent — its equity is reduced to zero. Bloating its balance sheet with deposits and reserves does not help this — and in fact increased the subordination of other classes of liabilities that rank behind deposits in a liquidation scenario. Deposits would flee to safer banks.

The main effect of QE was psychological — market participants were convinced that it was “money printing,” and used central bank balance sheets as a story to “explain” risk market gyrations.

External Sector

Some people (particularly emerging market analysts) have a bee up their bonnet about foreign investment. Apparently, foreign bond market vigilantes have the ability to unbalance a domestic financial system.

However, these concerns are invariably over-played for fiat currencies (not counting the euro as a true fiat currency). Each currency creates its own closed accounting system. If we replace domestic bond holders with foreign private sector bond holders, it is unclear why their portfolio allocation properties would be wildly different. The exception is foreign official currency reserves — as governments may switch their reserve allocations for political reasons. Nevertheless, the large size of many reserve positions limits their flexibility, and the domestic central bank can easily offset their transactions.

(Making the currency convertible — such as gold convertibility — creates a way to destroy financial assets in one currency and replace them with another. As seen historically, this can easily be destabilising.)

Savings and Growth

The possibility that financial markets are effectively self-financing is deeply unpopular. Many financial market participants want to believe that they are doing something useful for society, and politicians want to justify handing over power to financial markets. The typical argument is that by boosting financial markets, we will deliver stronger growth.

Properly understood, the role of financial markets is to price risks, and hopefully end up with an allocation that leads to sustainable investment and therefore growth. They also allow circular cash flows to be reinvested in this more sensible pattern. The problem with under-developed financial markets is that lending gets concentrated in a handful of badly managed banks, badly managed direct investment in firms or real estate, or else leaks into overseas markets. Once the dysfunctions are under control, the financial markets only have a limited effect on growing the pie, rather they just make sure the pie is somewhat edible.

It is possible to generate strong growth with a minimal non-bank financial system, as Germany and Japan demonstrated after World War II. The problem with a bank-dominated system is the herding behaviour of banks. Lending against fixed investment is a lot easier when you have the American consumer hoovering up all your exports. But once the easy lending opportunities are gone, banks have a tendency to all go over the credit cliff at the same time. Offloading concentrated credits on the portfolios that can absorb those losses allows the banking system to concentrate on whatever its alleged skills are.

Concluding Remarks

Industrial capitalism is not a system where people push around a fixed amount of “money.” Instead, capitalist economies melt upward (until the process reverses, usually temporarily). The act of lending grows liabilities and assets, and those assets end up being traded away.

The role of banks is to understand the liquidity flows created by asset allocation trends, and to tap into them to fund their own balance sheet. 

Email subscription: Go to https://bondeconomics.substack.com/ 

(c) Brian Romanchuk 2024

The UK’s missing companies

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Wed, 17/04/2024 - 5:36pm in

I posted this video on YouTube and elsewhere this morning:

In case the video does not show, the link is here.

The transcript is:

We do not know what at least half the companies in the UK are doing, which is absolutely staggering when those companies may exist to undertake fraud and abuse us.

Why is this possible? Well, because it is so easy to form companies in the UK. You don't even have to physically sign a form to pay £12, get Companies House to incorporate your company, and then you have what is in effect licensed identity theft, which you can hide behind to undertake fraudulent activity, collect money, trade without ever having any intention of telling the Revenue that you are, not pay your taxes, then throw your company away at the end of a year or so, and form a new one.

How do I know this is happening? Well, because, the data from Companies House shows it. There are 5.3 million companies in the UK at the time that I'm recording this. Of those, half a million are being got rid of at the moment – meaning nearly 10 per cent of all companies in the UK are currently in the course of being dissolved - many of them by Companies House because they've lost touch with the companies in question. Many more will be because they paid £10 to say they don't trade any more, and could they please be struck off? and please don't ask any questions because that's, in effect, what happens. We are literally letting these companies trade without telling HM Revenue and Customs.

How do I know that? Well, in the last year for which we've got data, HMRC only got corporation tax returns from three million companies of whom one quarter weren't trading. So that leaves only 2. 2 million or so companies which were actually declaring that they had positive income, of which only 1.5 million said they were actually making profits. About 160,000 said they were making losses, and the rest said they were getting other income like interest, rents, or dividends, for example as companies within groups. But what we do, therefore, know is that the majority of the companies in the UK aren't actually paying any tax at all, and you have to ask why they exist.

I know the answer to some extent. I've been a director of a company that never traded because it existed to protect the name of a website. So, yes, that's possible. But those companies should be filing tax returns. They should also be filing full accounts, which I admit Companies House is now beginning to address.

But they're not getting the data to HM Revenue and Customs. There are two ways to get around this. One is to make directors of companies that don't declare their tax liabilities personally responsible for the taxes they evade. It would be simple, straightforward, and fair to do that. After all, they're the people who are cheating.

Secondly, get our banks to tell HM Revenue and Customs every year which companies in this country they supply services to, who runs them, and tell HM Revenue and Customs how much they bank for that company and what the bank balance was at the end of the year. Then we'd know which companies who are not declaring their income need to be chased and who might be liable for the money that's owed.

We could do that.

If we did, we'd have fair competition, we'd have fairer taxation, and we'd stop this criminogenic environment existing which is undermining the fair trading of honest people in the UK. And we'd have a more vibrant economy as a result.

So why aren't we doing it? I just don't know because it would pay for a better society in every way that I can imagine.

There is much more on this in the Taxing Wealth Report 2024.

The Bank of England’s got it in for us

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Tue, 16/04/2024 - 11:07pm in

I just posted this video on TikTok and YouTube:

The Bank of England has never said it wanted to create a recession, a cost-of-living crisis and unemployment in the UK, but that is exactly what it is doing, but that is exactly what it is doing. Why is the government letting this happen?

I am aware that the embedding of this video has proved problematic. It can be found on YouTube here.

Why do we give the Bank of England so much power?

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Tue, 16/04/2024 - 4:19pm in

Andy Haldane’s contribution to public debate since leaving the Bank of England has not been as significant as I think many hoped it might be given that he enjoyed a reputation as one of its more enlightened monetary policy setters whilst working at the Bank as its chief economist.

That said, this final paragraph from an article on inflation and economic forecasting in the FT this morning is good:

John Kenneth Galbraith famously said economics was extremely useful — as a method of employment for economists. The same could be said of inflation forecasts and central bankers. For all Bernanke’s sound analysis, forecasting is likely to remain interpretive dance — always mysterious, occasionally enlightening, a show without much tell.

Of course, Haldane is referring to Ben Bernanke’s review of the Bank of England’s forecasting techniques, which I have already reviewed somewhat negatively here. 

Haldane is also negative, which leads to the obvious question as to why he spent so much of his life dedicated to the task he now treats with such contempt.

Saying that, it’s hard to disagree with Galbraith, as usual. But in that case, and given the massive flaws in most central bank estimates, meaning that in general the quality of their forecasting is abysmally poor for reasons I noted in my previous piece, why do we give them so much power?

Ben Bernanke’s review of the Bank of England was doomed from the outset because he didn’t ask the right questions

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Sat, 13/04/2024 - 3:53pm in

There has been lots of comment in the media on the criticisms that former chair of the US Federal Reserve and economics Nobel prize winner, Ben Bernanke, has made of the Bank of England’s forecasting techniques. He undertook a review of these methods at the invitation of the Bank because so much concern has been raised about how poor their forecasting has been, particularly since the Covid crisis.

In general, observers have suggested that Bernanke must have been thorough because he has made twelve recommendations for what people think to be significant reforms within the Bank. Bank of England boss, Andrew Bailey, has already said that he will act upon them. That, however, to me is the surest sign that Bernanke has missed his target. If he had suggested anything that would have created real change Bailey might have resisted his recommendations a lot more obviously.

A long time ago a wise person taught me that I should, when reading reports of this nature, not consider what is said within them, but what is left unsaid, meaning that an issue has been ignored. It is in this light that I have read the report.

Before noting those exceptions let me make it clear that I am unsurprised that he has said that (and I am summarising his twelve, heavily overlapping, recommendations when noting these issues):

  1. The Bank’s methodologies are out of date.
  2. The Bank’s technology is outmoded.
  3. The Bank is over-reliant on data analysis.
  4. The Bank has structures that do not encourage the promotion of expertise.
  5. There has been resistance to change within the Bank.
  6. Critical thinking that challenges the Bank’s forecasting has been discouraged, even in the Monetary Policy Committee.
  7. The Bank’s systems are orientated to processing normality, and not exceptions to the norm.
  8. There is a bias against narrative explanation of the Bank’s opinions and forecasts.
  9. Its reporting methods might be familiar due to their habitual use but they are not necessarily useful.

I stress, this is not how Bernanke puts things; I offer these as reasonable interpretations of what he says. To me they say that the Bank:

  1. Is outmoded in its thinking.
  2. Has failed to invest despite the enormous resources available to it.
  3. Requires compliant obsequiousness from its staff.
  4. Does not encourage critical thinking.
  5. Hides behind opacity.
  6. Lacks creativity.
  7. Most of all, is seeking to reinforce what it thinks it knows rather than what might actually be happening.

Again, I stress he did not say that: it is what I think he means.

That said, there are, in my opinion, major failings in what Bernanke has done. For example, has not questioned the basis of the economic approach adopted by the bank, which is based on what is described as dynamic stochastic general equilibrium modelling (DGSE). This is unsurprising. Bernanke is deeply invested in this economic method methodology, as all central bankers are. However, the model is profoundly unsound. There are a number of reasons.

Firstly, the model is based upon microeconomic foundations. It assumes that the model of decision-making that is appropriate for individuals, households and companies is also appropriate for the state. To put this another way, the household analogy is built into it from the outset. The result is an inherent logic that the government is just another player within the economy when it is nothing of the sort. It role is not only normally the inverse of all other actors within the economy, it also sets the rule for everyone else.

There is another problem arising from the use of microeconomic foundations. Many of the crass assumptions within microeconomics, including that markets can produce optimal outcomes and that they can clear supply and demand, are implicit in DGSE modelling, quite inappropriately. You cannot build sound economic forecast on the basis of nonsense. Bernanke does not say this.

Secondly, although it is claimed that these mathematical models can handle uncertainty, I do not think that is true. They can only handle risk, which is probabilistic. I am not convinced that they can handle uncertainty, to which probability cannot be attached, although it happens, nonetheless. This is why they were quite unable to handle the global financial crisis of 2008 and the Covid crisis. Those events simply did not exist within the range of forecast probabilities. Bernanke does not point this out.

Third, these models assume that there is such a thing as equilibrium, i.e. an optimal economic outcome to which we can aspire. There is no evidence that such a state as ever been achieved. In that case, why it is appropriate to assume that this is the basis for forecasting is very hard to explain. Bernanke offers no such explanation.

Fourth, as Steve Keen has explained, relentlessly, models of this sort are based upon the assumption of a barter economy where there is no role for money. Any adaptations within the model to include the role of money are necessarily a fudge. Why the Bank is using such a model to control monetary policy is hard to explain.

Fifth, if, instead of an equilibrium state being modelled there is instead a model that presumes that the status quo prevails (which Bernanke implies to be the case), then the model has built within it an assumption of reversion to the norm. That would be great if that norm was what everyone desired, but very clearly the norm within the economy in which we all live at present is not working. That means that the model is inherently in conflict with society - and what is happening in the real world.

Sixth, the most massive macroeconomic externality, in the form of climate change, is effectively ignored within this model, because that is what its microeconomic foundation necessitates. This fact pretty much undermines just about everything the Bank does.

I could go on, but I think that my reservations are now clear. I am, of course, aware of that I am generalising, but I also know that in almost every model of this sort where adaptation is introduced to try to accommodate the criticisms made, the assumption is that the exception from the model’s requirements is contrary to economic well-being i.e. the model always tries to make prediction that resort to its implicit over-riding assumption that pure market economies must exist, fundamentally free of government interference. The reality that a central bank exists to implement government policy is in fact contrary to the implicit assumptions in the models that presume that no such thing should happen.

Bernanke mentions none of this. As a result what he says will fail us.

But that was also guaranteed for another reason. It would appear from the commentary that he has provided that he spoke to no one, at least of consequence, outside the Bank when undertaking his work. In other words, he has made recommendations for reform of the way in which the Bank works without ever once considering the opinion, or needs, of the Bank’s stakeholders, whether they be the government, other politicians, society at large, or business of all sizes. His comments do, therefore, represent the ultimate statement of central banker arrogance. In the opinion of central bankers, nothing but their view matters. Bernanke did not say this, but whether he recognises it or not, it is clear that he thinks it.

Bernanke was always the wrong person for this job. He was a central banker marking another central banker’s homework, without ever questioning the assumptions on which the central bank worked. This investigation was doomed from the outset as a consequence.

And these are the people that Rachael Reeves is placing her faith in to run the economy when a Labour government is in office.

Some things don’t change much……

Published by Anonymous (not verified) on Fri, 08/03/2024 - 6:02pm in

Tags 

Banking

From Yes Minister:

Superbly written and acted, as usual.

Pages